1 / 18

Chapter 6

Chapter 6. Intertemporal Equilibrium Models. CAPM assumes a myopic behavior of investors, who optimize the. portfolio value at the next period only. An extension is to allow for. dynamic portfolio management. This chapter relates asset prices to.

maree
Download Presentation

Chapter 6

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 6 Intertemporal Equilibrium Models CAPM assumes a myopic behavior of investors, who optimize the portfolio value at the next period only. An extension is to allow for dynamic portfolio management. This chapter relates asset prices to the consumption and investment and saving decisions of investors.

  2. 6.1 Intertemporal equilibrium model Consumption: on a representative good with quantity Ct and price qt at time t. Income: External income Rt and αt shares on stocks with price St. Budget constraint: qtCt = Rt − (αt − αt−1)T St. Intertemporal choice problem: Let δ be the subjective dis- count factor. An individual wants to maximize wrt αt the dis- counted expect utility  Et   δjU (Ct+j) , ∞ j=0 subject to the budget constraint.

  3. Equivalent problem: With respect to portfolio allocation αt+j, ∞ j=0 Rt+j − (αt+j − αt+j−1)T St+j qt+j δjU max Et . Note that αt appears in the first two terms. The first-order condition can be obtained by taking derivative wrt αt and setting it to zero, −EtU (Ct) · St/qt + δEtU (Ct+1)St+1/qt+1 = 0. Euler condition: St = Et[Mt+1St+1], where Mt+1 is Stochastic δU (C )q t qt+1 Remark: — The price of each asset Si,t = Et[Mt+1Si,t+1], 1 = Et[Mt+1(1 + Ri,t+1)],

  4. where Ri,t+1 is the return at period t + 1. The price depends on *** inflation rate qt+1/qt, which can sometimes be ignored. *** intertemporal rate of substitution δU (Ct+1)/U (Ct). — If there exists a risk-free asset with return rf , then EtMt+1 = (1 + rf,t+1)−1. An extension of this is the existence of “zero-beta” asset, which is defined as S0,t satisfying: Covt(S0,t+1, Mt+1) = 0. Hence, S0,t = EtMt+1S0,t+1 = (EtMt+1)(EtS0,t+1). — The price of the ith stock is Si,t+1 1 + rf,t+1 Si,t+1 1 + rf,t+1 ∗ Si,t = Et Mt+1 /EtMt+1 = Et .

  5. where E∗ is the expectation with the conditional probability density of Mt+1/EtMt+1. Pricing probability or risk-neutral probability: The current asset price is the expected discounted future price with respect to the pricing probability dPt∗ dPt Mt+1 EtMt+1 = .

  6. 6.2 Comsumption-Based CAPM Individual demand: If assets and good prices are identical for all individuals, we have St = Ej,t[Mj,t+1St+1]. — The stochastic discount factors vary across individuals. — The individuals have different expectations, assess to information various time preference and different income patters. — It is hard to aggregate individual demands for financial assets and consumptions goods to derive the condition of equilibrium of ag- gregate demand and supply. Representative investor and equilibrium condition:

  7. Assume that there is a representative investor who has rational ex- pectation (The Euler condition): St = Et[Mt+1St+1], which can be applied at the aggregate level. Consumption-based CAPM(CCAPM): qt qt+1 U (Ct+1) U (Ct) St = Et δ St+1 . — qt is a retail price index, which can be ignored for simplicity. — Ct is the aggregate consumption of physical goods and services. — Et, δ and U are those of the representative investor.

  8. Note that St = (EtMt+1)(EtSt+1) + Covt(Mt+1, St+1). If there exists a risk-free asset with return rf , then St = (1 + rf )−1EtSt+1 + Cov(Mt+1, St+1). — Current price depends discounted present value and a risk pre- mium. — If an asset price evolves positively with the consumption growth (the discounted factor), investors need to pay a premium: The more assets are demanded for intertemporal transfers, the higher their prices.

  9. Commonly-used utility functions: — Exponential utility function: U (C) = − exp(−AC). C1−γ−1 1−γ (when γ → 1, U (C) = log C), — Power utility: U (C) = where γ is the coefficient of relative risk aversion. For this utility function: U (C) = C−γ and Ct+1 −γ Ct qt qt+1 St = Et δ St+1 or δEt exp Rt+1 − log qt+1/qt − γ log Ct+1/Ct = 1, where Rt+1 is the vector of log-returns: Rt+1 = log St+1/St — componentwise division.

  10. Remark: If Y = log X ∼ N (µ, σ2), then X has a log-normal dis- tribution. Furthermore, EX = EeY = exp(µ + σ2/2) Let Y t+1 = Rt+1 − log(qt+1/qt) − γ log(Ct+1/Ct). If Yi,t+1 is normally distributed, with the power utility function, 1 2 or 1 2 (1) δ exp{EtYi,t+1 + Vart(Yi,t+1)} = 1. EtYi,t+1 = − log δ − Vart(Yi,t+1).

  11. This yields the Hansen-Singleton (1983) formula: 1 2 1 2 assuming the inflation is negligible, where ∆Ct+1 = log Ct+1/Ct. Riskless return: For the riskfree asset, from (1), we have Vart(Y0,t+1) ≈ Var(γ∆Ct+1). Hence, by (2), γ2 2 rf,t+1 ≈ − log δ + γEt∆Ct+1 − Vart(∆Ct+1). It explains the factors that determine the riskless rate: the time preference rate (log-discount factor) “− log δ”, expected consumption

  12. growth (incentive to borrow for future consumption) and volatility of the growth (the representative agent has precautionary motive for saving). Using the Hansen-Singleton formula (2), the expected excess return 1 1 Et(Ri,t+1 − rf,t+1) ≈ − Vart(Yi,t+1) + Vart(Y0,t+1) 2 2 1 1 = − Vart(Ri,t+1 − γ∆Ct+1) + Vart(−γ∆Ct+1). 2 2 Excess return: Et[Ri,t+1 − rf,t+1] = −σi2/2 + γσic, where σi2 = Vart(Ri,t+1) and σic = Cov(Ri,t+1, ∆Ct+1). If the asset is positively correlated with the consumption growth, its expected return tends to be higher.

  13. Table 6.1: Moments of consumption growth and asset returns Variable Consumption growth Stock return CP return Stock − CP return Mean 0.0172 0.0601 0.0183 0.0418 Standard deviation 0.0328 0.1674 0.0544 0.1774 Correlation with consumption growth 1.0000 0.4902 -0.1157 0.4979 Covariance with consumption growth 0.0011 0.0027 -0.0002 0.0029 Consumption growth is the change in log real consumption of nondurables and services. The stock return is the log real return on the S&P 500 index since 1926, and the return on a comparable index from Grossman and Shiller (1981) before 1926. CP is the real return on 6-month commercial paper, bought in January and rolled over in July. All data are annual, 1889-1994. Let us illustrate the above pricing formula by using the following empirical data, from 1889-1994. The commercial papers with 6-month maturity are used the proxy of the riskless asset. The consumptions refer to those of nondurables and services. Expected excess return: log rE ∼ N (0.0418, 0.17742)

  14. ErE = exp(0.0418 + 0.17742/2) = 1.0592. The real return has expected value about 6% with an SD 18%. Risk aversion coefficient 0.0418 + 0.16742/2 = γ · 0.0027 =⇒≈ 19. This explains somewhat the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott (1985): the average excess return on the US stock market is too high to be easily explained by standard asset pricing model. They considered value of γ up to 10, which is too small to fit the data.

  15. Risk-free rate: γ2 2 · 0.03282. 0.0183 = − log δ + γ · 0.0172 − =⇒ δ ≈ 1.12. This is called the riskfree rate puzzle by Weil (1989): — Given a positive average consumption growth, a low riskless interest rate and a positive rate of time preference, such investors would have a strong desire to borrow from the future. — A low riskless interest rate is possible in equilibrium only if investors have a negative rate of time preference that reduces their desire to borrow. In some other studies, γ needs to be much larger to fit the data. For

  16. example, with γ = 29, δ < 1. Mean-Variance frontier∗ 6.3 Value of a portfolio: Wt = αTt St. Let Wt+1 = αTt St+1. Then from CCAPM, St = EtMt+1St+1, we have Wt = EtMt+1Wt+1 = Covt(Mt+1, Wt+1) + (EtMt+1)(EtWt+1). If there is a risk free asset, EtMt+1 = (1 + rf,t+1)−1. Thus, EtWt+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Wt = Covt(Mt+1, Wt+1)(1 + rf,t+1). By the Cauchy-Schwartz inequality (3) (EtWt+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Wt)2 Vart(Wt+1) Vart(Mt+1) (EtMt+1)2 ≤ .

  17. Efficient frontier: Excess gain (return) per unit risk (the Sharpe ratio) is bounded by Vart(Mt+1)/(EtMt+1) which is not always achievable. Question (Hansen and Jagannathan, 1991): Is there another stochastic discount factor Mt∗+1 such that St = Et[Mt∗+1St+1], and the Sharpe ratio is attainable? Construction: Let Mt∗+1 = α∗t T St+1 where α∗t minimizes Et(Mt+1 − αTt St+1)2. Note that Et(Mt+1 − α∗t T St+1)St+1 = 0. Thus, EtMt∗+1St+1 = EtMt+1St+1 = St. For any portfolio, its Sharpe ratio is bounded by Vart(Mt∗+1) (EtMt∗+1)2 (EtWt+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Wt)2 Vart(Wt+1) ≤ .

  18. Benchmark portfolio: Mt∗+1 attains the maximum Sharpe ratio, called the benchmark portfolio. Excess return: EtWt+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Wt = Covt(Mt∗+1, Wt+1)(1 + rf,t+1). Excess gain of benchmark portfolio: EtMt∗+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Mt∗ = Vart(Mt∗+1)(1 + rf,t+1). Hence Covt(Mt∗+1, Wt+1) Vart(M +1) [EtMt∗+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Mt∗]. EtWt+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Wt = t∗ Beta pricing: The excess gain of any portfolio is β times the excess gain of the benchmark port- folios. In terms of return, Covt(Mt∗+1, Rt+1) Vart(M +1) [EtMt∗+1 − (1 + rf,t+1)Mt∗]. EtRt+1 − rf,t+1 = t∗ Sharpe-Lintner CAPM can be regarded as a stochastic discount model with the discount factor Mt∗+1 being the return of the market portfolio.

More Related