1 / 17

Chapter 6

Chapter 6. Pollution control: instruments. MC. 200. MC B = 3Z B. . MC A = 3Z A. 100. . 75. . . . . . . . . . . . 5. Z. 10. 15. 20. 25. 30. 35. 40. Pollution abatement, Z. Figure 6.1 Marginal abatement cost functions for the two firms.

hdion
Download Presentation

Chapter 6

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 6 Pollution control: instruments

  2. MC 200 MCB = 3ZB  MCA = 3ZA 100  75            5 Z 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Pollution abatement, Z Figure 6.1 Marginal abatement cost functions for the two firms

  3. Figure 6.2 Expected damages, reducing as the amount of precaution taken, Q, increases • Expected damages • The amount of precaution taken, Q

  4. B(Q) C(Q) • Figure 6.3 • The socially efficient level of precautionary behaviour Precaution, Q Q* The level of precaution applied is socially efficient when the net benefit (B – C) from precaution is maximised. This is shown at Q = Q*. Note that the slopes of the B and C functions are equalised at this point. Hence, as shown in the lower half of the graphic, the marginal quantities are equated. That is, the marginal benefit of precaution and the marginal cost of precaution are equal at the socially efficient level of precaution, Q*. That is, MB(Q*) = MC(Q*). MC(Q) MB(Q) Precaution, Q Q*

  5. Ambient pollution levels Location of emissions Emissions output Quantity of goods produced Production technique Inputs used Figure 6.4a The pollution process

  6. Ambient pollution requirements Zoning Emissions licenses Output quotas Technology controls Input restrictions Figure 6.4b Command and control instruments

  7. Marginal damage Marginal benefit (before tax) Marginal benefit (after tax) * 0 Emissions, M M* Figure 6.5 An economically efficient emissions tax Marginal cost of abatement Marginal benefit of abatement * 0 Z* = Emissions abatement, Z Figure 6.6 The economically efficient level of emissions abatement

  8. Pre-tax or pre-subsidy marginal benefit Post-tax or post-subsidy marginal benefit . . . 0 Emissions, M Figure 6.7 Emissions tax and abatement subsidy schemes when marginal damage is unknown, or when a target is being set on grounds other than economic efficiency Suppose that the EPA does not have sufficient information to deduce the economically efficient level of emissions, or it wishes to set an overall emissions target on some other basis. Figure 6.7 makes it clear that to attain ANY specific emissions target using a tax or subsidy instrument, knowledge of the aggregate (pre-tax or pre-subsidy) marginal benefit of emissions function would be sufficient.

  9. Pre-tax or pre-subsidy marginal benefit Marginal damage Post-tax or post-subsidy marginal benefit S5 * S1 S3 S6 S2 S4 0 Emissions, M M* Figure 6.8 Emissions tax and abatement subsidy schemes: a comparison An emissions tax and an emissions abatement subsidy (at the same rate) differ in terms of the distribution of gains and losses. This has important implications for the political acceptability and the political feasibility of the instruments. It also could affect the long-run level of pollution abatement under some circumstances, via alteration of the size of the industry.

  10. A firm will bid to purchase an additional emissions permit whenever the marginal cost of abating emissions exceeds the permit price. The market equilibrium permit price is determined by the value of the aggregate marginal abatement cost at the level of abatement implied by the total number of issued permits. Marginal abatement cost (aggregate) Fixed supply of permits * 0 M* Emissions, M Figure 6.9 The determination of the market price of emissions permits Auctioned permits case

  11. Demand for permits Supply of permits * 0 EP* Emission permits (EP) Figure 6.10 The determination of the market price of emissions permits: free initial allocation case

  12. Marginal abatement cost Figure 6.11: Efficient abatement with two firms and marketable permits 200 180 MC(B) 160 140 Equilibrium permit price = Marginal abatement cost for MC(A) 120 each firm = 75 100 MC(INDUSTRY) 80 60 40 20 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 Emissions abatement, Z Required industry wide abatement Under tradable permit schemes, in equilibrium marginal abatement costs will be equal over all firms. Hence marketable permits, like taxes and subsidies, achieve any given target at least cost. Moreover, if the total quantity of permits issued is M* and that quantity is identical to the level of emissions which would emerge from an emissions tax (or an abatement subsidy) at the rate * then a marketable permit scheme will generate an equilibrium permit price *.

  13. .2 .1 Controlled sector .4 .3 .6 .5 Firm 3, one of six controlled large power station sources of CO2 Figure 6.12.a A ‘cap and trade’ permit system

  14. .A Uncontrolled sectors (of other CO2 emitters) .2 .1 Controlled sector .C .A .4 .3 .6 .B .D .5 Firm 3, one of six controlled large power station sources of CO2 Figure 6.12.b A flexible permit system with offsets

  15. Figure 6.13 Dynamic incentives under emissions tax controls £ MC1 MC2    0 Z2* Z1* Emissions abatement, Z

  16. Ci i • • Figure 6.14 The firm’s abatement cost function.

More Related