1 / 29

RAINS and Chapter 14

RAINS and Chapter 14. ECON 4910. The Rains Model. An example of applied environmental economics. Illustrates how economic theory is translated into a real world model. The lack of data makes compromises necessary. This implies a few warts. What is captured by the RAINS model?.

lilliec
Download Presentation

RAINS and Chapter 14

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. RAINS and Chapter 14 ECON 4910

  2. The Rains Model • An example of applied environmental economics. • Illustrates how economic theory is translated into a real world model. • The lack of data makes compromises necessary. • This implies a few warts.

  3. What is captured by the RAINS model? • Several versions of the model, some with sulphur, NOx, ammonia etc. • Here we focus on the sulphur model.

  4. Components of the Rains model • 38 regions (For the most part countries). These are the sources of pollution, ei. • 700 grid squares covering Europe, each 150 km ×150 km. These are receptors of pollution, dj. • A meteorolocial model, a matrix where the coefficent aij is the fraction of pollution from i that ends up in j. dj = Σiaij ei + bj bj is exogenous depositions from sources not covered in the model. Mainly United States

  5. More components of the Rains model • Ecological consequences – A function that maps depositions into ecological consequences – fraction of ecosystems in a grid square that is severly damaged. • These functions are called critical loads. The 5% critical load implies that 5% of ecosystems will be destroyed or damaged. • Stepwise function (Draw figure on Board)

  6. The cost module • For each source there is a purification cost curve ci(ei). • Purification is the cost of reducing emissions keeping output constant • Marginal cost curves in steps. • Represented by ci = iei + Bi

  7. The model • Minimise ∑ci j=1,2 … , 38 • subject to ci ≥iei + Bi dj = Σiaij ei + bj ≤ Di i = 1,2,…,700 Di are usually n% critical loads. That is we allow 5% of the ecosystems in each grid to be destroyed or severly damaged

  8. Feasibility • Turns out 5% critical loads are not feasible. (Can’t be done) • Question is: How to modify the model? Let us try Gap Closure for the non-feasible constraints. • dj≤ σ(dj(historical) – Dj) + Dj. • Here σ is the ”percentage of closure” • Alternative: Area exceedance closure

  9. Now Questions • What compromises have been made? • Exogenous output • No valuation of damages. Arbitrary protection at 5% of ecosystems. • Gap Closure not even related to ecosystem protection • So, is this a good model?

  10. Economy-Wide effects • Into macro-economics and the effect of environemental regulation on total productivity. • Issue # 1. How does environmental protection affect productivity. • Issue # 2. How does environmental protection affect our measures of productivity

  11. Productivity growth • Production grows for three reasons: • Increased use of inputs (such as labor and capital) • Increased efficiency • Technological progress • Problem right here. Production must be measured properly, i.e. include environmental services. However, all three may lead to less production of environmental services.

  12. Total Factor Productivity Growth • Consider the macro production function Y=Af(L,K). • Here A is a technology variable assumed to capture the effect of progress. (Einsteins theory of relativity, The Slutsky Equation and the invention of Tofu.)

  13. Some manipulations to decompose productivity growth • Differentiate to get ΔY = ΔAf(L,K) + AF’LΔL + AF’KΔK Divide by Y to get: ΔY/Y = ΔA/A + (LAF’L/AY)(ΔL/L) + (KAF’K/AY)(ΔK/L) Use that pL = pYAF’Land pK = pYAF’K. and zero profits in macro equilibrium to get:

  14. Finally… ´ • Á/A = Ý/Y – sLĹ/L – sKK/K Here sL = pLL/(pLL + PKK) and sK = pKK/(pLL + PKK) sK and sL are cost shares. Technological growth Á/A is the increase in production not attributed to increased input use.

  15. The effect on prouctivity when we look at a bad measure • Productivity growth is often reported only as Labour productivity growth. • What is the effect of environmental regulations that raises the price of capital?

  16. Green National Accounting • Why national accounting? • Indispensable tool for planning purposes. Macroeconomic policy without national accounting does not make much sense. • Important metric for people with a size fetish. My GDP is bigger than your GDP. • For both purposes it is important to get things right.

  17. Example - China • Example - China • • GDP per capita in 2004: US$ 5600 • • US GDP per capita in 2004: US$40100 • • So USA is more than 7 times as rich as • China • • China GDP per capita grew at 9.1% in 2004 • • USA grew at 4.4% • • If this continues…

  18. But something is a amiss • Each year 400000 Chinese die from airpollution • 70% of China’s freshwater is polluted to the point of being undrinkable • These things are not measured

  19. What can go wrong with national accounting • Some things are not measured correctly or at all • Goods not produced for sale in a market e.g. raising kids, house cleaning, pollution induced health problems. • Goods that are produced by government e.g. the value of education • Prices do not reflect social cost • Some things are categorized wrong. • Extraction of natural resources such as fish and oil represents (possibly) depletion of wealth rather than production of income.

  20. National Accounting • Y = C + G + I + A – B. • GDP equals Consumption + Real Investment + Financial Investment through trade surplus. All measured at market prices. • Here we only consider a closed economy without a government.

  21. Deriving GDP measure from a Optimally Managed Economy • Consider the following economy: • Utility W=∑tU(ct)βt with Kt+1 – Kt = F(Kt,Rt) – δKt – ct and Et+1 – Et = f(Et) – Rt • Lagrangian for this problem is • Λ= ∑t(U(ct)βt – λ(Kt+1 – Kt – (F(Kt,Rt) – δKt) – ct) – μ (Et+1 – Et – (f(Et) – Rt)) • R is a natural resource

  22. Deriving GDP measure from a Optimally Managed Economy • Let us look at the first term in the Lagrangian: (U(c0)β0 – λ(K0+1 – K0 – (F(K0,R0) – δK0) – ct) – μ (E0+1 – E0– (f(E0 ) – R0 )) Does it look familiar? • How about now? (U’()c0β0 – λ(K0+1 – K0 – (F(K0,R0) – δK0) – ct) – μ (E0+1 – E0– (f(E0 ) – R0 ))

  23. The point: • If the market prices are equal to the shadow prices and to marginal utility, GDP for period t is equal to the corresponing term in the Lagrangian! This can be shown formally but is a bit tricky. • (U’()c0β0 – λ(K0+1 – K0 – (F(K0,R0) – δK0) – ct) – μ (E0+1 – E0– (f(E0 ) – R0 )) = • (pc0 – pK(Capital investment) – pE(Change in resource stock))

  24. A wrongly calculated GDP • (pc0 – pK(Capital investment) + pE(Resource extraction)) • Two errors are made. Resource extraction counts as positive when it should be negative (and vice versa) • Note: In a steady state economy this does not matter.

  25. The relationship between wealth and GDP • It can be proven that if NNP is measured correctly then: • Wealth = NNP/Discount rate • An increase in NNP implies higher utility

  26. Issues not touched upon: • Adjusting GDP for risk? Catastrophic risk. The easy way is NNP + Pr(catastrophe in a year)×Cost of catastrophe • – Risk distributed across population. Very contested topic • – Income distribution?

  27. Income distribution • Although China is growing rapidly, a largepart of the population is left behind. • Imposes political risk on future NNP development. • Is a dollar to Farmer Poor Joe the same as a dollar toBill Gates? • Is distributionally skewed NNP growth sustainable?

  28. Income distribution - USA • From 1985 to 2003, the richest 1% saw an increase in income equal to 60% (adjusted for inflation) • From 1985 to 2003, the richest 1% saw an increase in income equal to 2% (adjusted for inflation) • Based on tax returns. The truth is even worse. • Recipe for revolution

More Related