1 / 30

Rational Constrained Choice and Computing Ordinary Demands

This text explains the concept of rational constrained choice and how to compute ordinary demands in economics using different examples, including Cobb-Douglas preferences and corner solutions.

klegault
Download Presentation

Rational Constrained Choice and Computing Ordinary Demands

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter Five Choice

  2. Rational Constrained Choice x2 More preferredbundles Affordablebundles x1

  3. Rational Constrained Choice x2 (x1*,x2*) is the mostpreferred affordablebundle. x2* x1 x1*

  4. Rational Constrained Choice • When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0 the demanded bundle is INTERIOR. • If buying (x1*,x2*) costs $m then the budget is exhausted.

  5. Rational Constrained Choice x2 (x1*,x2*) is interior.(a) (x1*,x2*) exhausts thebudget; p1x1* + p2x2* = m. x2* x1 x1*

  6. Rational Constrained Choice x2 (x1*,x2*) is interior .(b) The slope of the indiff.curve at (x1*,x2*) equals the slope of the budget constraint. x2* x1 x1*

  7. Rational Constrained Choice • (x1*,x2*) satisfies two conditions: • (a) the budget is exhausted; p1x1* + p2x2* = m • (b) the slope of the budget constraint, -p1/p2, and the slope of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

  8. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. • Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences. • Then

  9. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. • So the MRS is

  10. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. • So the MRS is • At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so (A)

  11. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. • (x1*,x2*) also exhausts the budget so (B)

  12. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. • So now we know that (A) (B)

  13. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. • So now we know that (A) Substitute (B)

  14. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. • So now we know that (A) Substitute (B) and get This simplifies to ….

  15. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

  16. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. Substituting for x1* in then gives

  17. Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. x2 x1

  18. Rational Constrained Choice • But what if x1* = 0? • Or if x2* = 0? • If either x1* = 0 or x2* = 0 then the ordinary demand (x1*,x2*) is at a corner solution to the problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint.

  19. Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Subtitutes Case x2 MRS = -1 x1

  20. Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case x2 MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2. x1

  21. Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case x2 MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2. x1

  22. Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case x2 MRS = -1 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 < p2. x1

  23. Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case x2 Better x1

  24. Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case x2 Which is the most preferredaffordable bundle? x1

  25. Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case Notice that the “tangency solution”is not the most preferred affordablebundle. x2 The most preferredaffordable bundle x1

  26. Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 x2 = ax1 x1

  27. Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 The most preferred afforablebundle x2 = ax1 x1

  28. Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2} x2 (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m(b) x2* = ax1* x2 = ax1 x2* x1* x1

  29. Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*. Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives

  30. Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case (a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*. Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives The cost of a bundle of 1 unit of commodity1 and a units of commodity 2 is p1 + ap2;m/(p1 + ap2) is the largest affordable numberof such bundles.

More Related