1 / 48

The Mathematics of Elections Part I: Apportionment

The Mathematics of Elections Part I: Apportionment. Mark Rogers (a.k.a. The Mad Hatter). The Mechanics of Elections. Any system of electing representatives is essentially a two-stage process:

ianna
Download Presentation

The Mathematics of Elections Part I: Apportionment

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Mathematics of ElectionsPart I: Apportionment Mark Rogers (a.k.a. The Mad Hatter)

  2. The Mechanics of Elections • Any system of electing representatives is essentially a two-stage process: • Apportionment: how we determine how many representatives there should be and how those representatives are to be distributed among various subgroups of the population as a whole • Voting: how we choose which candidate(s) should be chosen as those representatives

  3. The United States Congress • Defined in Article I of the U.S. Constitution • Consists of two chambers • The House, the apportionment of which is proportional to a state’s population • The Senate, which is not • The apportionment also affects the presidential elections. • The Electoral College weight of each state is equal to its combined House and Senate delegation. • The Senate is comprised of two members from each state, regardless of population.

  4. The 108th Congress

  5. The 110th Congress

  6. The House of Representatives • Originally defined as 65 members for the original 13 states; currently 435 members, plus 5 non-voting delegates for territories • The only Constitutional requirements for apportionment are that each state gets at least one Representative, that the general distribution be based on population, and that each person in the House represent at least 30,000 residents of their state. • The original proposed First Amendment would have imposed a stepwise function for future expansions of the House’s size, but it was never ratified. • Instead, acts of Congress have governed each increase.

  7. “Article the First” (proposed 1789) • Proposed as the first of 12 amendments to the new Constitution • If the House began to exceed 100 seats, the distribution would shift to one per 40,000 residents. • If the House began to exceed 200 seats, the distribution would shift to one per 50,000 residents. • Like the Congressional-raise-limiting “Article the Second,” it was never ratified by a sufficient number of states at the time. • The other ten amendments became the Bill of Rights.

  8. How many Representatives is too many? • “Nothing can be more fallacious than to found our political calculations on arithmetical principles. Sixty or seventy men may be more properly trusted with a given degree of power than six or seven. But it does not follow that six or seven hundred would be proportionably a better depositary. And if we carry on the supposition to six or seven thousand, the whole reasoning ought to be reversed. The truth is, that in all cases a certain number at least seems to be necessary to secure the benefits of free consultation and discussion, and to guard against too easy a combination for improper purposes; as, on the other hand, the number ought at most to be kept within a certain limit, in order to avoid the confusion and intemperance of a multitude.” • James Madison

  9. Average Constituency • The typical number of voters an official represents • “The Constitution…must be understood, not as enjoining an absolute relative equality, because that would be demanding an impossibility….That which cannot be done perfectly must be done in a manner as near perfection as can be.” • Daniel Webster, 1832

  10. How many Representatives is too many? • Around the world, the number of legislators (and thus, the average constituency for each) varies widely. • U.S.: 435 Representatives, for 305,532,000 people (for an average of 702,000 constituents each) • China: 3,000, for 1,326,940,000 people (442,000 each) • India: 552, for 1,139,910,000 people (2,000,000 each) • San Marino: 60, out of 30,800 people (513 constituents per legislator) • Nauru: 18, out of 10,000 people (556 constituents each)

  11. A House (Re)Divided • Traditionally, new states were admitted to the Union with their appropriate number of Representatives (typically, a small number at the outset) added to the old total. • With each Census, the House size would be readjusted (usually upward), and the various states’ delegations redistributed accordingly. • 1790: 65 Representatives for 3.9 million people in 13 states • 1793: 105 Representatives for 4.3 million in 15 states • 1813: 182 Representatives for 8.0 million in 18 states • 1873: 292 Representatives for 42 million in 37 states • 1893: 356 Representatives for 67 million in 44 states

  12. Minimizing “unfairness” • Apportionment Criterion: When assigning a representative among several parties, make the assignment so as to create the smallest possible relative unfairness.

  13. Minimizing “unfairness” • State legislatures could once redraw Congressional districts (as well as their own) in any manner desired, whether “fair” or not, most often to favor rural areas over more populous urban areas. • House Speaker Sam Rayburn (D-TX) (1882-1961) was able to have a rural district with just 227,735 residents, while a Houston Congressman’s had 806,701 residents. • Had the district lines been “fair,” the Houston area would have been entitled to three to four times as many Representatives as Rayburn’s rural area. • State-house districts often had similar disparities as great as 1000 to 1. • Vermont: 35 residents in one district, 36,000 in another

  14. “One man, one vote”(Well…“One person, one vote”) In Reynolds v. Sims (1964), the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that the Constitution’s Equal Protection Clause established a “one man, one vote” principle, requiring each district within a state to have the same size constituency. Wesberry v. Sanders (1964) extended this principle to Congressional districts as well. Districts would thus need to be redrawn as the population relocated over time.

  15. “One Man, One Vote” • As a result, Congressional districts will vary quite a bit in size, but must be reasonably equal in population. • Sparse rural areas vs. dense, multi-Representative urban areas

  16. “Gerrymandering” • Term for redistricting designed to favor or hinder one particular group • “packing”: concentrating the members of a group into one district to increase their voting influence to a majority, or to limit their voting influence to it alone • “cracking”: dividing the members of a group among several districts, in none of which can they muster a majority, to dilute their voting influence • Elbridge Gerry (1744-1814): governor of Massachusetts, whose Congressional districts were redrawn in a convoluted manner to benefit his party

  17. “Gerrymandering” • The Boston Gazette lampooned the shape of one district with an editorial cartoon likening it to a mythical creature, the “gerrymander.”

  18. “Gerrymandering” • Numerous districts of Congress have been redrawn in elaborate, spindly shapes, such as the Texas 22nd and Illinois 4th shown below. • Congressional districts must be contiguous in shape, but can do so using tendrils, even as thin as a highway, to connect several regions.

  19. “Gerrymandering” • Rep. Tom DeLay (R-TX) pushed through a special re-redistricting of the Texas Congressional districts in 2003, following his party’s takeover of the state legislature after 140 years. • Just 2 years after the previous redistricting • The new map merged two incumbent Democrats into one district, forcing one out of Congress. • It also divided up urban areas among the surrounding suburbs, limiting their influence.

  20. “Gerrymandering” • Rep. Frank Mascara (D-PA) was forced to run (unsuccessfully) against colleague John Murtha after statehouse Republicans redrew boundary lines to move him from his old district into Murtha’s. • A tendril of Murtha’s new district extended down a street to envelop Mascara’s house, though not his driveway. • The process can also act to increase influence. • Western states were carved out of sparsely populated territories to maximize their presidential impact, since each state would get at least 3 Electoral College votes (due to having one Congressman plus two Senators) regardless of population.

  21. “Gerrymandering” • One effect of the Voting Rights Act of 1965 was to create a series of “majority-minority” districts, to redress cases of past discrimination. • In a series of cases in the 1990s, the U.S. Supreme Court banned gerrymandering based solely on a racial basis. • However, in 2006, the Court let the Texas redistricting stand, ruling that gerrymandering done merely to benefit one political party was constitutional. • The decision also upheld repeated redrawing of district lines, not just those done after each Census. • Recent redrawings of district lines have been done by bipartisan panels to insure that both parties enjoy “safe” districts that they are unlikely to lose. • 2002: a record-low four incumbents lost their re-election bids

  22. The effects of “gerrymandering” • In this example, the “state” has 4 legislative districts and 64 residents, 36 “green” and 28 “purple.” • By having 44% of the population, the purple residents would deserve 1 or 2 representatives. • In the first map, the purple residents are concentrated into one central district, insuring they will dominate it but have little influence in others.

  23. The effects of “gerrymandering” • In the second map, the central area is expanded to incorporate the other purple voters, forming an area large enough to justify two purple-majority districts. Both they and the two “green” districts are virtually homogenous (and thus “safe”). • In the third map, the purple residents are split up among the 4 districts, in each of which they are outnumbered 9 to 7. (The result: no purple-majority districts.) • In the fourth map, the (minority) purple residents are split up so as to form a 9-7 majority in three districts.

  24. The Hamilton Method of Apportionment • A longtime method of apportionment for the House, introduced by Alexander Hamilton (1755-1804) and adopted in 1852 • A modification of the basic method of allocating delegates by assigning each group or state an appropriate percentage of the total number of representatives • Find the percentage of the total population contained in each state or group. • Multiply each percentage by the number of representatives, rounding down (to avoid potentially allocating more representatives than are available). • Award any remaining representatives based on which group’s “fair number” of them was rounded down the most.

  25. Now You See Them, Now You Don’t • A study of potential expansions of the House following the 1880 Census revealed a curious paradox. • If the House were to have 299 Representatives, Alabama would be entitled to 8 of them. • However, if the House were expanded to 300 Representatives, Alabama would be entitled to only 7! • In other words, as the House gains an extra delegate, Alabama would lose one, even though its percentage (and that of every other state) had not changed. • This became known as the Alabama paradox. • Appendix: See Excel spreadsheet “Census Apportionments.”

  26. Curiouser and Curiouser • The curious paradox was almost seen ten years earlier, in the wake of the 1870 Census. • If the House were to have 270 Representatives, Rhode Island would be entitled to 2 of them. • However, if the House were expanded to 280 Representatives, Rhode Island would be reduced to a single one! • Tiny but densely populated, Rhode Island had never had a single Representative since the dawn of the Republic. • Appendix: See 1870 tab on “Census Apportionments.”

  27. Who’s Got It In For The South? • The “Alabama paradox” was also seen again just ten years later, following the 1890 Census. • If the House were to have 359 Representatives, Arkansas would be entitled to 7 of them. • However, if the House were expanded to 360 Representatives, Arkansas would be entitled to just 6! • The paradox arises from attempting to reallocate previously assigned representatives to states whose growth rates are not in sync, rather than simply allocating any newly added ones. • Appendix: See 1890 tab on “Census Apportionments.”

  28. Watch Closely • Some examples were extreme in their alignment-of-the-planets timing, such as the case of Colorado following the 1900 Census. • A careful study was undertaken of every potential House size from 350 to 400 Representatives. • In almost every case, Colorado was entitled to 3 Representatives. However… • If the House were placed at exactly 357 members, Colorado would get only 2. • Worse than a 356-member House, and worse than a 358-member House! (357 was the only case like this.) • Upon hearing this, one Illinois Congressman tried to have 357 specifically chosen as the number of House seats. (Jerk.) • Appendix: See 1900 Census tab on “Census Apportionments.”

  29. Up and Down • Attempts to replace Hamilton’s method with an alternative similarly caused Maine’s delegation to fluctuate in size. • “Now you see it and now you don’t. In Maine comes and out Maine goes. The House increases in size and still she is out. It increases a little more in size, and then, forsooth, in she comes….God help the state of Maine when mathematics reach for her and undertake to strike her down in this manner.” • Rep. Charles Edgar Littlefield (R-Maine) • Littlefield retired almost immediately afterward.

  30. A Simpler Example • Suppose there are 47 faculty members in the sciences, 37 in the humanities, and 16 in the professional and trade schools. • A 9-person faculty committee is to be formed. • Using Hamilton’s method, we find the “fair” number of seats each division deserves, round down any decimals, and choose how to allocate any remaining seats afterwards.

  31. The 9-Person Faculty Committee • Now suppose that the committee is to be expanded to 10 seats. We will use Hamilton’s method to reapportion the seats.

  32. The 10-Person Faculty Committee • The professional faculty’s “fair” number of representatives has indeed grown, but not as fast as the other two divisions, both of which have now overtaken them in the “who’s been rounded down the most?” category.

  33. The Other Founding Fathers • Thomas Jefferson, John Adams, and Daniel Webster each proposed alternatives to Hamilton’s method. • In each of their methods, the total population of the state (which helps us find us the percentage of the total representatives the state is entitled to) is replaced by either a smaller or larger number. • This is done not to affect the state’s fair share, but to make the numbers work out more easily.

  34. Alternatives to Hamilton’s method • Jefferson’s method: • “Decrease” the total population figure (thus increasing the expected number of representatives) • Round the “number of representatives deserved” down • Repeat until the correct number of delegates is awarded • Adams’s method: • “Increase” the total population figure (thus decreasing the expected number of representatives) • Round the “number of representatives deserved” up • Repeat until the correct number of delegates is awarded • Webster’s method: • Find an alternative total population figure by trial and error • Round the “number of representatives deserved” up or down, according to the normal rules of rounding • Repeat until the correct number of delegates is awarded

  35. Representative Quotas • The “number of representatives deserved” in Hamilton’s method is referred to as the standard quota. • Rounding down, we obtain the lower quota. • Rounding up, we obtain the upper quota. • If an apportionment allocates each state a number of representatives between its lower and upper quotas, then it is said to satisfy the quota rule. • In other words, a state that “deserves” 5.37 representatives should receive either 5 or 6, not 3 or 7. • Hamilton’s method is the only one of the four “Founding Fathers” methods that does not violate this principle, since we added single extra representatives to some states after rounding down their standard quotas. • The others’ altered total population figures give them an “undeservedly” higher or lower number of “deserved” representatives.

  36. More Problems for Hamilton • Were the rarity of the Alabama paradox the only problem Hamilton’s method risked, it might still be used today. However, there are a number of other paradoxes that can occur with it. • Population paradox: State A’s population is growing faster than state B, yet A loses a representative to B. • A’s percentage population growth was higher than B’s, but Hamilton’s method only takes into account the raw-number differences (which would have been higher if B was a larger state to begin with). • New states paradox: When a new state (and its share of new seats) are added to the legislature, another state’s (previously allocated) seats can end up reassigned. • Similarly, this new dilution of representation affects each state equally on a raw-number basis, which in turn hits smaller states harder on a percentage basis (causing their “partial representative” numbers to fall further).

  37. In Maine Comes, Out She Goes • In 1907, Oklahoma became the 46th state. Mindful of its rapid oil-boom growth, the long time since the 1900 Census, and the previous cases of the Alabama paradox, Congress chose to simply add the 5 new Representatives it “deserved” to the previous 386, and reallocate based on old Census data. • However, a new paradox emerged. • In a 386-member House, New York was entitled to 38 seats, but…. • In a 391-member House, New York lost one of its seats to Maine, delaying an expected loss of Maine’s 4th seat for another twenty years. • In the absence of a new Census, no other population figures had been adjusted, yet New York still lost out to Maine. • It was the new states paradox; adding Oklahoma’s seats “on top” of the others had changed the delegates for other states. • Appendix: See 1907 tab on Excel spreadsheet “Census Apportionments.”

  38. The Huntington-HillApportionment Principle • Developed for FDR by mathematicians Edward Huntington and Joseph Hill • Huntington: inaugural President of the Math. Assoc. of America • Hill: Assistant Director of the U.S. Census • Their method has been used for House reapportionment since 1941. • Avoids the Alabama paradox by assigning each representative one at a time, back from the very beginning • In essence, it calculates the unfairness of each state’s current number of representatives, and compares it to the unfairness of that state’s number of representatives if an extra one were added.

  39. The Huntington-HillApportionment Principle • To find the Huntington-Hill number, calculate for each state or group: • The formula comes from a rearranged comparison of the relative unfairness of two competing proposed allocations. • Whichever state has the highest Huntington-Hill number should be given the next new representative to be added in order to minimize the relative unfairness.

  40. Building From The Ground Up • Under the Huntington-Hill method, each group or state is given one representative at the start. • Then, all other representatives are allotted one at a time based on which group or state has the highest Huntington-Hill number at that moment. • California, with a massive population (squared) figure, receives both the 1stand 3rd bonus seats awarded, as well as the 6th, 12th, and 15th. • The “usual suspects” of large states receive the other early ones. • California’s 53rd district and North Carolina’s 13th are the last two seats to be awarded in a 435-member House. • By a tiny margin, Utah narrowly missed out on a fourth seat. • Utah sued the Census Bureau unsuccessfully, arguing that irregularities in Census tabulations (and undercounting of their own Mormon missionaries) should have entitled them to the final seat. • Appendix: See “Huntington-Hill” Excel spreadsheet.

  41. The Faculty Committees, When Using The Huntington-Hill Method • We use this table of Huntington-Hill numbers to award the 9 (or 10, or any other number) of committee seats to the various faculty divisions, in descending order of the H-H numbers (wherever it appears in the table). • By not stopping to reconsider old seat apportionments, we will never take away one group’s seat to give it to another.

  42. Coming Soon • Population projections for the 2010 Census suggest that the trend of migration from the industrial Midwest to the South and Southwest will continue, resulting in continued shifts in House seats. • Utah will finally get its extra seat. • Others gaining a seat: GA, NV, NC, OR, SC • Arizona and Florida will each gain 2 seats, Texas 4. • States losing a seat: CA, IL, IA, LA, MA, MI, MN, MO, NJ, PA • New York and Ohio will each lose 2 seats.

  43. The Wyoming Rule • No matter the system used to divide up the House seats, all states are guaranteed at least one, regardless of population; thus, Wyoming with its 522,830 residents gets one Representative, as does Montana, with its 957,861 residents. • Montana’s population is far too small to justify a second Representative. • Wyoming is frankly too small to justify a single one, but the Constitution mandates it. • The Wyoming Rule is a proposal to avoid this “low-end” unfairness of large-state constituencies far exceeding the small single-Representative constituency of small-population states. • It would increase the size of the House until the average constituency in each state matched that of the least populous state. • If the Wyoming Rule were enacted, the House would need to increase to at least 585 members. • Colorado: currently 7 Representatives, would increase to 9 • California: currently 53 Representatives, would increase to 70 • Montana: currently 1 Representative, would increase to 2

  44. The Ugly Conclusion • Given the many paradoxes, the question arises: • Can any method of apportionment avoid all of them? • Is there a “perfect” method of apportioning representatives? • In 1980, Michael Balinski and H. Peyton Young found the answer. • Balinski and Young’s Impossibility Theorem: There is no apportionment method that avoids all paradoxes and at the same time satisfies the quota rule.

  45. Webster was right! • “The Constitution…must be understood, not as enjoining an absolute relative equality, because that would be demanding an impossibility….That which cannot be done perfectly must be done in a manner as near perfection as can be.” • Daniel Webster, 1832

  46. Does It Make A Difference? • The 1876 presidential election was bitterly contested, as Rutherford B. Hayes (R) trailed Samuel Tilden (D) by 19 electoral votes, with 20 electoral votes from three southern states in dispute. • Congress voted to award the disputed electoral votes to Hayes, giving him a 185-184 victory. • Republicans had reportedly agreed with southern states to end Reconstruction-era troop garrisons in exchange for their support. • Years later, Balinski and Young showed that had a different apportionment method been used, Tilden’s lead would have held.

  47. What have we learned? • Dividing up a group of representatives is not easy. • Robert Burns said it best: “The best-laid plans of mice and men often go awry.” • In a world of paradoxes and unmet quotas, no method is perfect. • Even when the seats have been assigned fairly, they may not be divided up within a group fairly. • Small changes can have a major impact, mathematically and historically. • All of this tells us very little about the next phase of the election process: voting. • Now that the council’s seats have been divided up, how do we decide who gets to fill them? • Next Friday: The Mathematics of Elections, Part II: Voting.

  48. References • Most liberal-arts college-mathematics course (ex.: MATH 110) textbooks • Including ours, Thomas L. Pirnot’s Mathematics All Around, 3rd edition • Alex Bogolmony’s interactive paradox explorer, at www.cut-the-knot.org/ctk/Democracy.shtml • Census information: www.census.gov • (in particular, the stats of www.census.gov/compendia/statab/) • Complete list of projections as to which states “deserve” the first 440 Representatives using the Huntington-Hill method: www.census.gov/population/censusdata/apportionment/00pvalues.txt • Interactive electoral maps, both historic and modern: www.270towin.com • Analysis of 2000 Presidential election given different House sizes, at www.thirty-thousand.org/pages/Neubauer-Zeitlin.htm • And yes, of course, Google and Wikipedia. • My Mesa State homepage, at www.mesastate.edu/~mcrogers, will have this presentation plus the spreadsheets used.

More Related