1 / 65

Liang Wu & Isabel Yan City University of Hong Kong

Measuring Market Expectations on Federal Funds Target Rate. Liang Wu & Isabel Yan City University of Hong Kong. 1. Agenda. Background of Fed funds market Literature review Existing models on Fed funds rate and their limitations Model set up Model evaluations Conclusions.

helen
Download Presentation

Liang Wu & Isabel Yan City University of Hong Kong

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Measuring Market Expectations on Federal Funds Target Rate Liang Wu & Isabel Yan City University of Hong Kong

  2. 1. Agenda • Background of Fed funds market • Literature review • Existing models on Fed funds rate and their limitations • Model set up • Model evaluations • Conclusions

  3. 2. Background - Fed funds target rate • Federal funds market: • banks borrow from or lend to, one another on an unsecured basis the reserves balances that they hold at the Fed Reserve accounts. • (b) Effective Fed Funds rate (FFR) = volume-weighted daily average overnight rate • The Federal Reserve Bank of New York collects data on the overnight trades • arranged each day by the major brokers in this market and uses the data to • calculate a volume-weighted daily average overnight rate. • (c) FOMC directs NY Fed to maintain, on average, • effective FFR = target rate (FFR*) • using open market operation. FFR Target error FFR* FOMC meeting

  4. 2. Background (Con’t)

  5. 3. Review on Fed funds models • Fundamental Approach --- Taylor Rule: • conventional(Taylor,1993), • smoothing (Clarida et al., QJE 2000; Rudebusch, 2002), • Bayesian VAR (system of equations on FFR, real time nonfarm payrolls and core CPI (Gurkaynak et al., 2007) Findings: (i) Real time data availability (Orphanides, 2001) (ii) Output gap hard to measure reliably - various trends and filters (Orphanides and Norden, 2002; Orphanides, Reifschneider, Tetlow and Finan 1999) - output gap uncertainty affects optimal parameters in the policy rule (Smets, 1999) (iii) Time-varying parameters Fed may change the weighting on inflation, unemployment (Cochrane and Piazzesi, AER 2002). (iv) Use of real-time data makes it difficult to determine the correct dynamics (Rudebusch, 1998, 2001, JME 2002b)

  6. (2) Market-based Approach Advantages: (a) Surmounting the omitted-variables and time-lag problems: Market expectations from liquid financial instruments can summarize the vast amount of information used by Fed in setting policy, and used by Fed- watchers in guessing Fed’s actions. (b) Overcome the time-varying parameter problem Financial instruments used: (a) Fed Funds Futures: spot-month (Krueger and Kuttner, 1996; Faust, Swamson and Wright, 2004); month-ahead (Bomfim, 2003; Poole and Rasche, 2000) (b) Others: Eurodollar futures: 1-month (Cochrane and Piazzessi, 2002); 3-month (Rigoben and Sack, 2002) Yield spread: Lange, Sack and Whiteshell (2001); Rudesbusch (2002); Piazzessi, 2005.

  7. Findings: (i) Market-based approach is superior to the Fundamental Approach: • Even static forecast performs better than the Taylor rule with Greenbook forecasts. • Models using yield curve is better than the conventional Taylor rules (Piazzesi, 2001, 2005). • All of the financial instruments are clearly superior to the Bayesian VAR (Gurkaynak et al., 2007) (ii) Among financial instruments in the market-based approach, Fed funds futures dominate all the other instruments at horizons out to six months (Gurkaynak et al., 2007) (iii) For longer horizons, the predictive power of many of the instruments become more similiar (Gurkaynak et al., 2007)

  8. (3) Risk-adjusted futures rate --- the hybrid approach • Adjust the risk premium term by business cycle variables such as non-farm payroll (Piazzesi and Swanson, 2008) Findings: (i) Risk premia are well predicted by macro-economic indicators in real time (ii) The risk-adjusted approach is better than the rule-of-thumb-adjusted approach that is currently used by the Fed

  9. Figure 1. Fed Funds Futures Rates – Target Rates Limitations in the Literature (a) The maturity value of the Fed funds futures is linked to the monthly averageeffective Fed funds rate, not specifically on the new target rate for the upcoming FOMC meeting. Objective #1 of this paper: To somehow undo the time-averaging to get a correct measure of the expectation on the new target rate in the upcoming FOMC meeting. (b) Use only the N-month futures contract for a N-month-ahead forecast. Hasn’t used the information embedded in the futures contracts of other horizons, Objective #2 of this paper: To obtain more expectation information by using the whole spectrum of futures contracts of different horizons.

  10. Why is it useful to forecast the target rate instead of just the monthly average? • Starting from Feb. 1994, the FOMC began to inform the public about the scheduled meeting and announced the target rate immediately after the meeting. The practice has dramatically changed how market participants form their expectations: (i) There was a structural break in February 1994 in the response of T-bill rates to the Fed funds target. The term rates react much in unison during the announcement days after 1994 (Demiralp and Jorda, 2004) (ii) The behavior of the U.S. prime rate changed significantly from before 1994 to after 1994. Until 1994, the US prime rate is irresponsive to short-term interest rate changes. After 1994, prime rate has come to react immediately to shifts in target rate. (Kobayashi, 2009) Since 1994, the focal point of the market has changed to the target rate instead of the smoothed version of the interest rate.

  11. 4. Model set up (recursive identification approach) month: tt+1t+2t+3 As in Piazzesi and Swanson (2008), we sample the futures data on the last day of the month.

  12. Scenario(A): 1-Month-Ahead Expectations month tt+1 weight on old target rate weight on new target rate

  13. Based on this relationship, we can extract the market expectation of the 1-month ahead new target rate by “purging” the carried-over effect of the old target rate from the 1-month-FFF: Target errors should have an expected value of 0 because the FOMC directs the Federal Reserve Bank of New York (the Desk) to maintain the overnight Fed funds rate “at an average of around” the target rate(see Hilton, 2005).

  14. Day of the month Figure 3. FOMC meeting day frequency, Feb.1994 – Sept. 2008

  15. Scenario(B): 2-Month-Ahead Expectations month tt+1t+2

  16. Scenario(C): 3-Month-Ahead Expectations month: tt+1t+2t+3

  17. sub. Into 3-month-ahead expectation

  18. sub. from 2-month-ahead expectation

  19. Scenario(D): 4-Month-Ahead Expectations Given We can obtain

  20. Scenario(E): 5-Month-Ahead Expectations Given and so on up to the 4-month-ahead expectations, we can obtain …

  21. Scenario(F): 6-Month-Ahead Expectations Given and so on up to the 5-month-ahead expectations, we can obtain…

  22. 4.2 Features of the “recursive identification” approach • The use of the recursive identification approach is expected to yield better prediction of the target rate than using the N-month futures rate alone, especially in the short-horizon when the bias caused by the risk premium term is smaller. • However, in the longer horizon, the effect from the leveraged risk premia is expected to accumulate whichcan drive a bigger wedge between the expectation and the realized target rate. • The leverage effect on the risk premium will magnify if the FOMC meetings are held close to the end of the month.

  23. 4.3 Method to alleviate the leverage effect when the FOMC meetings are held close to the end of the month tt+1t+2 (no meeting)t+3 • There are four months in a year when there are no scheduled meeting. • During these months the target rate is the same as the target rate after the • previous month’s FOMC meeting. • Usually the FOMC meeting before a non-meeting month takes place near • the end day of the month. • The leverage effect is close to maximum if we use the n-month futures • contract to recover the n-month-ahead target rate. • In this case, the (n+1)-month futures contract gives a better forecast for the • n-month-ahead target rate, as it is not suffered from the leverage effect. 4.3 Technical details (A) Forecast of the target rate when the FOMC meeting is close to the end of the month, and when there is no meeting in the subsequent month

  24. We therefore propose an end-of-the-month modified strategy if and there is no FOMC scheduled meeting in month t+1. • For instance, at one-month forecast horizon, there are 11 cases in which the expected monetary policy rate using the recursive identification approach is more than 25 bps away from the actual target rate. • In these circumstances, 7 out of the 11 cases are when the FOMC meeting happened in the last 2 days of the month. • The modified strategy gives better predictions in all these cases. Table 1. Observations with 1-month-ahead forecast errors greater than 25 bps

  25. 5. Evaluations of the recursive identification approach (RI approach) Does the average effective FFR anchor to the expected target rates derived from the RI approach? • Test the cointegrating relationship: If the expectations derived from the RI approach are good predictors of the target rates to which the effective fed funds rates anchor to, we expect:

  26. Cointegration Estimation Results

  27. 6. Out-of-Sample Forecasts I.Static Forecast: Using the previous meeting’s target rate as the forecast II. Taylor Rule: Forecast version of Clarida et al. (2000), III. Futures-alone: Directly using (100 - futures price) as the forecast value, adjusted by the end-of-the-month alternative strategy IV. Risk-adjusted futures: Using futures, and adjusting for risk premia using real time business cycle variables (non-farm payroll and total capacity utilization). V. Recursive identification approach:

  28. Technical details for obtaining the risk-adjusted futures rates (Piazzessi and Swanson, 2008) Step 1: Regress the proxy for risk premium on real-time business cycle variables: Step 2: run rolling window regressions to get out-of-sample forecast for the risk premium term, then subtract it from the fed funds futures:

  29. For the Taylor rule and risk-adjusted futures rates, we use half of the sample (55 data points) for in-sample training, and then use the obtained estimated coefficient to forecast the next out-of-sample point. The first out-of-sample forecast is for January, 2001. • All macroeconomic variables are based on real-time data.

  30. 6.1 Evaluations of the Out-of-Sample Prediction Performance (a) Root Mean Square Error (RMSE) (b) Modified Diebold-Mariano (MDM) test (Harvey et al., 1997) It compares the out-of-sample forecast residuals of two models via the squared loss function L(.): (c) Regression of the actual target rate changes on the expected changes (d) Graphical analysis

  31. (a) Root Mean Square Error (RMSE) • the recursive approach has the best performance for 1- and 2- month-ahead forecasts. • (ii) the risk-adjusted approach always yields better results than directly • using the Fed funds futures • (iii) The recursive approach, the risk-adjusted approach and directly using • futures all outperform static forecasts. • (iv) static forecasts is very similar to the Taylor rule • (v) for longer horizon forecasts, the forecasting performances of the • recursive approach and the risk-adjusted approach are quite similar.

  32. (b) Modified Diebold-Mariano (MDM) test

  33. In terms of the MDM test, • The expectations extracted from the recursive approach significantly outperform the other candidates for 1- and 2-month-ahead forecasts. • The recursive approach, the risk-adjusted approach and directly using futures all outperform static forecasts. • Static forecasts are not significantly different from the Taylor rule. • For longer horizon forecasts, the recursive approach, the risk-adjusted approach and the futures-alone approach are not statistically different.

  34. (c) Regression of the actual changes on the expected changes If the expectations have good predictive power, we expect .

  35. In terms of the regression results, • The explanatory power (in terms of the ) is much higher for the market-based approaches than the fundamental approach (the Taylor rule). • The estimated slope coefficients of the recursive approach and the risk-adjusted futures are much closer to 1 compared with the futures-alone approach and the Taylor rule, suggesting that the expected changes track closer to the actual changes for these approaches. • The estimated intercepts of all three of the futures-based approaches are significantly negative, which is consistent with the fact that the expectation terms on the right hand side encompasses some (full or partial) risk premium which tends to bias up the expectations. • The estimated intercepts from the recursive approach is smaller than that of the futures-alone approach but are slightly larger than that of the risk-adjusted futures. • The estimated intercepts become smaller and less significant after we adjust the futures by the risk premium terms, suggesting that the risk adjustment procedure is useful in capturing at least part of the risk premium.

  36. The estimated intercepts from the futures-alone regression indicate that the average risk premium is about: 3 bp for 1 month (~3 bp per month), 6 bp for 2 months (~3 bp per month), 16 bp for 3 months (~ 5 bp per month), 22 bp for 4 months (~5.5 bp per month) 34 bp for 5 months (~7 bp per month) 28 bp for 6 months (~5 bp per month).

  37. (d) Graphical Analysis

More Related