1 / 65

Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance

Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance. ECN 741, Urban Economics. Professor John Yinger, The Maxwell School, Syracuse University , 2018. The Theory of Local Public Finance. Class Outline The U.S. Federal System The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance

dykema
Download Presentation

Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance ECN 741, Urban Economics Professor John Yinger, The Maxwell School, Syracuse University, 2018

  2. The Theory of Local Public Finance Class Outline • The U.S. Federal System • The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance • Deriving a Bid Function • Residential Sorting • Is the U.S. Federal System Efficient? Introduction

  3. The Theory of Local Public Finance Class Outline • The U.S. Federal System • The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance • Deriving a Bid Function • Residential Sorting • Is the U.S. Federal System Efficient? Introduction

  4. The Theory of Local Public Finance The U.S. Federal System • Constitutions and Politics • Broad outlines defined by constitutions • Details determined by politics • Units Defined by U.S. Constitution • The Federal Government • State Governments • Units Defined by State Constitutions • The State Government • Counties and (usually) Townships • Municipalities (Cities and Villages) • School Districts • Special Districts The U.S. Federal System

  5. The Theory of Local Public Finance CountyTownship Municipality School District Map of Hypothetical State The U.S. Federal System

  6. The Theory of Local Public Finance Source: U.S. Census of Governments The U.S. Federal System

  7. The Theory of Local Public Finance Class Outline • The U.S. Federal System • The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance • Deriving a Bid Function • Residential Sorting • Is the U.S. Federal System Efficient? Introduction

  8. The Theory of Local Public Finance Local Public Finance • The literature on local public finance in a federal system is built around three questions: • 1. How do housing markets allocate households to jurisdictions? = Bidding and sorting! • 2. How do jurisdictions make decisions about the level of local public services and taxes? • 3. Under what circumstances are the answers to the first two questions compatible? The Consensus Model

  9. The Theory of Local Public Finance The Role of Tiebout • This literature is often traced to a famous article by Charles Tiebout in the JPE (October 1956). • Tiebout said people reveal their preferences for public services by selecting a community (thereby solving Samuelson’s free-rider problem). • Tiebout said this choice is like any market choice so the outcome is efficient. • But Tiebout’s model is very simplistic. It has • No housing market • No property tax (just an entry fee) • No public goods (just publically provided private goods) or voting • No labor market or commuting (just dividend income) The Consensus Model

  10. The Theory of Local Public Finance Key Assumptions • This class focuses on a post-Tiebout consensus model for the first question based on 5 assumptions: • 1. Household utility depends on a composite good (Z), housing (H), and public services (S). • 2. Households differ in income, Y, and preferences, but fall into homogeneous income-taste classes. • 3. Households are mobile, so utility is constant within a class. • 4. All households in a jurisdiction receive the same S (and a household must live in a jurisdiction to receive its services). • 5. A metropolitan area has many local jurisdictions with fixed boundaries and varying levels of S. The Consensus Model

  11. The Theory of Local Public Finance Additional Assumptions • Most models use 2 more assumptions: • 6. Local public services are financed with a property tax with assessed value (A) equal to market value (V = PH/r, where r is the discount rate). • Let m be the legal tax rate and τ the effective rate, then tax payment, T, is and • 7. All households are homeowners or households are renters and the property tax is fully shifted onto them. The Consensus Model

  12. The Theory of Local Public Finance Class Outline • The U.S. Federal System • The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance • Deriving a Bid Function • Residential Sorting • Is the U.S. Federal System Efficient? Introduction

  13. The Theory of Local Public Finance The Household Problem • The household budget constraint is where τ* is defined to be τ/r. • The household utility function is: The Consensus Model

  14. The Theory of Local Public Finance The Household Problem 2 • The Lagrangian: • The first-order conditions: The Consensus Model

  15. The Theory of Local Public Finance The First-Order Conditions • The 1st and 2nd conditions imply: • The 3rd condition simplifies to: The Consensus Model

  16. The Theory of Local Public Finance The First-Order Conditions, 2 • The simplification in the first equation should be familiar from earlier topics in the class. • Because Z has a price of unity, the marginal rate of substitution between S and Z, US/UZ, is the marginal benefit of S in dollar terms, or MBS. The Consensus Model

  17. The Theory of Local Public Finance The Market Interpretation • These conditions indicate the values of S and τ that a household will select. • But all households cannot select the same S and τ! • Thus, these conditions must hold at all observed values of S and τ, that is, in all communities. • As in an urban model, this is called, of course, locational equilibrium. • No household has an incentive to move because lower housing prices exactly compensate them for relatively low values of Sor relatively high values of τ. • This is, of course, the issue that arises with commuting costs in a basic urban model. The Consensus Model

  18. The Theory of Local Public Finance Alternative Approach • Solve the budget constraint for Pandfind the most a household is willing to pay per unit of Hat a given utility level • NowPSand Pτcan be found using the envelope theorem. The results are the same! The Consensus Model

  19. The Theory of Local Public Finance Bidding for Property Tax Rates • These two conditions are differential equations. • The tax-rate equation can be written as • This is an exact differential equation which can be solved by integrating both sides to get: where C is a constant of integration. The Consensus Model

  20. The Theory of Local Public Finance Property Tax Rates, 2 • We can solve for C by introducing the notion of a before-tax bid, sometimes called the bid “net of taxes” and indicated with a “hat”: • Substituting this condition into the above (after exponentiating) yields: The Consensus Model

  21. The Theory of Local Public Finance Property Tax Rates, 3 • Note for future reference that we can differentiate this result with respect to S, which gives • This result makes it easy to switch back an forth from before-tax to after-tax bid-function slopes (with respect to S). The Consensus Model

  22. The Theory of Local Public Finance The House-Value Equation • To test this theory, we want to estimate an equation of the following form: • The dependent variable is house value, V, or it could be apartment rent. • The key explanatory variables are measures of public services, S, property tax rates, τ, and housing characteristics, X. The Consensus Model

  23. The Theory of Local Public Finance Capitalization • In this equation, the impact of τon V is called “property tax capitalization.” • The impact of S on V is called “public service capitalization.” • These terms reflect the fact that these concepts involve the translation of an annual flow (T or S) into an asset or capital value (V). The Consensus Model

  24. The Theory of Local Public Finance Finding a Functional Form • This house value equation cannot be estimated without a form for . To derive a form we must solve the above differential equation for P{S}: • To solve this equation, we obviously need expressions for MBSand H. • As in an urban model, these expressions require assumptions about the form of the utility function (which implies a demand function) or about the form of the demand function directly. Deriving a Bid Function

  25. The Theory of Local Public Finance Finding a Functional Form 2 • One possibility is to use constant elasticity forms: where the Ks indicate vectors of demand determinants other than income and price, and W is the price of another unit of S. Deriving a Bid Function

  26. The Theory of Local Public Finance Finding a Functional Form 3 • These forms are appealing for three reasons: • 1. They have been successfully used in many empirical studies. • Duncombe/Yinger (ITPF 2011), community demand for education • Zabel (JHE 2004), demand for housing • 2. They can be derived from a utility function. • The derivation assumes a composite good (=an “incomplete demand system”), zero cross-price elasticities, and modest restrictions on income elasticities [LaFrance (Journal of Agricultural Economics, August 1986)]. • 3. They are tractable! Deriving a Bid Function

  27. The Theory of Local Public Finance Finding a Functional Form 4 • Note that the demand function for S can be inverted to yield: • This is, of course, the form in which it appears in earlier derivations. Deriving a Bid Function

  28. The Theory of Local Public Finance Finding a Functional Form 5 • Now substituting the inverse demand function for S and the demand function for H into the differential equation yields: where Deriving a Bid Function

  29. The Theory of Local Public Finance Finding a Functional Form 6 • The solution to this differential equation is: where C is a constant of integration and the parentheses indicate a Box-Cox form, or, and Deriving a Bid Function

  30. The Theory of Local Public Finance Finding a Functional Form 7 • This equation is, of course, a “bid function.” • It indicates how much a given type of household would pay for a unit of H in a location with a given level of S. • It is analogous to the bid functions in a basic urban model—it indicates how much a household would pay at different locations (=levels of S) holding utility constant. Deriving a Bid Function

  31. The Theory of Local Public Finance Class Outline • The U.S. Federal System • The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance • Deriving a Bid Function • Residential Sorting • Is the U.S. Federal System Efficient? Introduction

  32. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting • It is tempting to stop here—to plug this form into the house value equation and estimate. • As we will see, many studies proceed, incorrectly, in exactly this manner. • But we have left out something important: sorting. • To put it another way, we have not recognized that households are heterogeneous and compete with each other for entry into desirable locations. Sorting

  33. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 2 • Sorting in this context is the separation of different household types into different jurisdictions. • As in an urban model, the key conceptual step to analyze sorting is to focus on P, the price per unit of H, not on V, the total bid. • In the long run, the amount of H can be altered to fit a household’s preferences. • A seller wants to make as much as possible on each unit of H that it supplies. Sorting

  34. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 3 • This framing leads to a standard picture in which is on the vertical axis and S is on the horizontal axis. • Each household type has its own bid function; that is, its own . • The household that wins the competition for housing in a given jurisdiction is the one that bids the most there. Sorting

  35. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 4 • Yinger (JPE, September 1982) was an early user of this picture (although not the inventor). His version (with E instead of S): P(E,t*) Sorting

  36. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 5 • Any sorting picture must distinguish between bid functions and envelopes. Here is another example: The envelope must slope upwards, but its second derivative, which reflects the balance between bidding and sorting, could be positive or negative . Sorting

  37. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 6 • The logic of this picture leads to several key theorems. • 1. Household types with steeper bid function end up in higher-S jurisdictions. • This important theorem indicates that sorting is determined by the slopes of bid functions. • It is illustrated in the following figure. Sorting

  38. The Theory of Local Public Finance Consensus Bidding and Sorting P P3 P2 P1 Group 2 lives in jurisdictions with this range of S. S2 S2 S1 S Sorting

  39. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 6 • This theorem depends on a “single crossing” assumption, namely, that if a household type’s bid function is steeper at one value of S, it is also steeper at other values of S. • This is a type of regularity condition on utility functions. Sorting

  40. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 7 • 2. Some jurisdictions may be very homogeneous in their demand for the amenity. • Sorting tends to separate households with different amenity demands. • This is clear in the above figure. Sorting

  41. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 8 • 3. But other jurisdictions may be very heterogeneous in their demand for the amenity. • In the standard picture, these jurisdictions may include those at the intersections between bid functions. • Or large cities may contain many household types. See the following figure. Sorting

  42. The Theory of Local Public Finance A Heterogeneous Jurisdiction P P3 P2 Four household types live in the jurisdiction where S = S1. P1 4 1 3 2 S2 S2 S1 S Sorting

  43. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 9 • 4. Sorting does not depend on the property tax rate. As shown above, • Nothing on the right side depends on Y (or any other household trait); starting from a given P, the percentage change in P with respect to τ is the same regardless of Y. Sorting

  44. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 10 • 5. In contrast, income, Y, (or any other demand trait) can affect sorting. • Because τdoes not affect sorting, we can focus on before-tax bids. • We will also focus on what is called “normal sorting,” defined to be sorting in which S increases with Y. Sorting

  45. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 11 • Normal sorting occurs if the slope of household bid functions increases with Y, that is, if • This condition is assumed in Yinger’sJPE picture. Sorting

  46. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 12 • After some rearranging, we find that • Normal sorting occurs if the income elasticity of MBS exceeds the income elasticity of H. Sorting

  47. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 13 • The constant elasticity form for S implies that • Hence, the slope, , will increase with Y so long as: Sorting

  48. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 14 • The available evidence suggests that θ and μ are approximately equal in absolute value and that γ≤ 0.7. • It is reasonable to suppose, therefore, that this condition usually holds. • Competition, not zoning, is the main reason that high-Y people live in high-S jurisdictions (although zoning may preserve existing patterns). Sorting

  49. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 15 • 6. This analysis of bidding and sorting applies to any public service or amenity that is linked to a location. • Examples include: • The perceived quality of local elementary schools; • Distance from a pollution source; • Access to parks or other neighborhood amenities. • As we will see, this framework also links nicely with the largely empirical literature on so-called hedonic regressions. Sorting

  50. The Theory of Local Public Finance Sorting 16 • 7. Finally, the logic of bidding and sorting does not apply only to the highly decentralized federal system in the U.S. • It also applies to any country in which • A location-based public service or neighborhood amenity varies across locations, • Housing markets are competitive and households can decide where to live, and • Access (or the cost of access) to the service or amenity depends on residential location. Sorting

More Related