1 / 43

Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance

Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance. ECN 741, Urban Economics Professor Yinger. Lecture Outline The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance Deriving a Bid Function Residential Sorting. Intro duction. The U.S. Federal System Constitutions and Politics

wren
Download Presentation

Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Bidding and Sorting: The Theory of Local Public Finance ECN 741, Urban Economics Professor Yinger

  2. Lecture Outline • The Consensus Model of Local Public Finance • Deriving a Bid Function • Residential Sorting Introduction

  3. The U.S. Federal System • Constitutions and Politics • Broad outlines defined by constitutions • Details determined by politics • Units Defined by U.S. Constitution • The Federal Government • State Governments • Units Defined by State Constitutions • The State Government • Counties and (usually) Townships • Municipalities (Cities and Villages) • School Districts • Special Districts The U.S. Federal System

  4. CountyTownship Municipality School District The U.S. Federal System

  5. The U.S. Federal System

  6. Local Public Finance • The literature on local public finance in a federal system is built around three questions: • 1. How do housing markets allocate households to jurisdictions? = Bidding and sorting! • 2. How do jurisdictions make decisions about the level of local public services and taxes? • 3. Under what circumstances are the answers to the first two questions compatible? The Consensus Model

  7. The Role of Tiebout • This literature can be traced to a famous article by Charles Tiebout in the JPE in 1956. • Tiebout said people reveal their preferences for public services by selecting a community (thereby solving Samuelson’s free-rider problem). • Tiebout said this choice is like any market choice so the outcome is efficient. • But Tiebout’s model is simplistic. It has • No housing market • No property tax (just an entry fee) • No public goods (just publically provided private goods) or voting • No labor market (just dividend income) The Consensus Model

  8. Key Assumptions • Today I focus on a post-Tiebout consensus model for the first question based on 5 assumptions: • 1. Household utility depends on a composite good (Z), housing (H), and public services (S). • 2. Households differ in income, Y, and preferences, but fall into homogeneous income-taste classes. • 3. Households are mobile, so utility is constant within a class. • 4. All households in a jurisdiction receive the same S (and a household must live in a jurisdiction to receive its services). • 5. A metropolitan area has many local jurisdictions with fixed boundaries and varying levels of S. The Consensus Model

  9. Additional Assumptions • Most models use 2 more assumptions: • 6. Local public services are financed with a property tax with assessed value (A) equal to market value (V). • Let m be the legal tax rate and τ the effective rate, then tax payment, T, is and • 7. All households are homeowners or households are renters and the property tax is fully shifted onto them. The Consensus Model

  10. The Household Problem • The household budget constraint • The household utility function The Consensus Model

  11. The Household Problem 2 • The Lagrangian: • The first-order conditions: The Consensus Model

  12. The First-Order Conditions • The 1st and 2nd conditions imply: • The 3rd condition simplifies to: The Consensus Model

  13. The Market Interpretation • These conditions indicate the value of S and τ that a household will select. • But all households cannot select the same S and τ! • Thus, these conditions must hold at all observed values of S and τ, that is, in all communities. • As in an urban model, this is called, of course, locational equilibrium. • No household has an incentive to move because lower housing prices exactly compensate them for relatively low values of Sor relatively high values of τ. • This is, of course, the issue that arises in a basic urban model. The Consensus Model

  14. Alternative Approach • Solve the budget constraint for P; find the most a household is willing to pay for Hat a given utility level • NowPSand Pτcan be found using the envelope theorem. The results are the same! The Consensus Model

  15. Bidding for Property Tax Rates • These two conditions are differential equations. • The tax-rate equation can be written as • This is an exact differential equation which can be solved by integrating both sides to get: where C is a constant of integration. The Consensus Model

  16. Property Tax Rates 2 • We can solve for C by introducing the notion of a before-tax bid, sometimes called the bid “net of taxes” and indicated with a “hat”: • Substituting this condition into the above (after exponentiating) yields: The Consensus Model

  17. Property Tax Rates 3 • Note for future reference that we can differentiate this result with respect to S, which gives • This result makes it easy to switch back an forth from before-tax to after-tax bid-function slopes (with respect to S). The Consensus Model

  18. The House Value Equation • To test this theory, we want to estimate an equation of the following form: • The dependent variable is house value, V, or it could be apartment rent. • The key explanatory variables are measures of public services, S, property tax rates, τ, and housing characteristics, X. The Consensus Model

  19. Capitalization • In this equation, the impact of τon V is called “property tax capitalization.” • The impact of S on V is called “public service capitalization.” • These terms reflect the fact that these concepts involve the translation of an annual flow (τ or S) into an asset or capital value (V). The Consensus Model

  20. Finding a Functional Form • This house value equation cannot be estimated without a form for . To derive a form we must solve the above differential equation for S: • To solve this equation, we obviously need expressions for MBSand H. • These expressions require assumptions about the form of the utility function (which implies a demand function) or about the form of the demand function directly. Deriving a Bid Function

  21. Finding a Functional Form 2 • One possibility is to use constant elasticity forms: where the Ks indicate vectors of demand determinants other than income and price, and W is the price of another unit of S. Deriving a Bid Function

  22. Finding a Functional Form 3 • These forms are appealing for three reasons: • 1. They have been successfully used in many empirical studies. • Duncombe/Yinger (ITPF 2011), community demand for education • Zabel (JHE 2004), demand for housing • 2. They can be derived from a utility function. • The derivation assumes a composite good (=an “incomplete demand system”), zero cross-price elasticities, and modest restrictions on income elasticities [LaFrance (JAE 1986)]. • 3. They are tractable! Deriving a Bid Function

  23. Finding a Functional Form 4 • Note that the demand function for S can be inverted to yield: • This is, of course, the form in which it appears in earlier derivations. Deriving a Bid Function

  24. Finding a Functional Form 5 • Now substituting the inverse demand function for S and the demand function for H into the differential equation yields: where Deriving a Bid Function

  25. Finding a Functional Form 6 • The solution to this differential equation is: where C is a constant of integration, the parentheses indicate a Box-Cox form, or, and Deriving a Bid Function

  26. Finding a Functional Form 7 • This equation is called a “bid function.” • It indicates how much a given type of household would pay for a unit of H in a location with a given level of S. • It is analogous to the bid functions in a basic urban model—it indicates how much a household would pay at different locations (=levels of S) holding utility constant. Deriving a Bid Function

  27. Sorting • It is tempting to stop here—to plug this form into the house value equation and estimate. • As we will see, many studies proceed, incorrectly, in exactly this manner. • But we have left out something important: sorting. • To put it another way, we have not recognized that households are heterogeneous and compete with each other for entry into desirable locations. Sorting

  28. Sorting 2 • Sorting in this context is the separation of different household types into different jurisdictions. • As in an urban model, the key conceptual step to analyze sorting is to focus on P, the price per unit of H, not on V, the total bid. • In the long run, the amount of H can be altered to fit a household’s preferences. • A seller wants to make as much as possible on each unit of H that it supplies. Sorting

  29. Sorting 3 • This framing leads to a standard picture in which is on the vertical axis and S is on the horizontal axis. • Each household type has its own bid function; that is, its own . • The household that wins the competition for housing in a given jurisdiction is the one that bids the most there. Sorting

  30. Sorting 4 • I did not invent this picture but was an early user. Here’s the version in my 1982 JPE article (where I use E instead of S): P(E,t*) Sorting

  31. Sorting 5 • The logic of this picture leads to several key theorems. • 1. Household types with steeper bid function end up in higher-S jurisdictions. Group 2 lives in jurisdictions with this range of S. Sorting

  32. Sorting 6 • This theorem depends on a “single crossing” assumption, namely, that if a household type’s bid function is steeper at on value of S, it is also steeper at other values of S. • This is a type of regularity condition on utility functions. Sorting

  33. Sorting 7 • 2. Some jurisdictions may be very homogeneous, such as a jurisdiction between the intersections in the following figure. Sorting

  34. Sorting 8 • 3. But other jurisdictions may be very heterogeneous, namely, those at bid-function intersections, which could (in another figure) involve more than two household types. Sorting

  35. Sorting 9 • 4. Sorting does not depend on the property tax rate. As shown above, • Nothing on the right side depends on Y (or any other household trait); starting from a given P, the percentage change in P with respect to τ is the same regardless of Y. Sorting

  36. Sorting 10 • 5. In contrast, income, Y, (or any other demand trait) can affect sorting. • Because τdoes not affect sorting, we can focus on before-tax bids. • We will also focus on what is called “normal sorting,” defined to be sorting in which S increases with Y. Sorting

  37. Sorting 11 • Normal sorting occurs if the slope of household bid functions increases with Y, that is, if • This condition is assumed in my JPE picture. Sorting

  38. Sorting 12 • After some rearranging, we find that • Normal sorting occurs if the income elasticity of MB exceeds the income elasticity of H. Sorting

  39. Sorting 13 • The constant elasticity form for S implies that • Hence, the slope, , will increase with Y so long as: Sorting

  40. Sorting 14 • The available evidence suggests that θ and μ are approximately equal in absolute value and that γ≤ 0.7. • It is reasonable to suppose, therefore, that this condition usually holds. • Competition, not zoning, explains why high-Y people live in high-S jurisdictions. Sorting

  41. Sorting 15 • 6. This analysis of bidding and sorting applies to any public service or amenity that is linked to a location. • Examples include: • The perceived quality of local elementary schools; • Distance from a pollution source; • Access to parks or other neighborhood amenities. • As we will see, this framework also links nicely with the largely empirical literature on so-called hedonic regressions. Sorting

  42. Sorting 16 • 7. Finally, the logic of bidding and sorting does not apply only to the highly decentralized federal system in the U.S. • It also applies to any country in which • A location-based public service or neighborhood amenity varies across locations, • Housing markets are competitive and households can decide where to live, and • Access (or the cost of access) to the service or amenity depends on residential location. Sorting

  43. Preview • In the next set of classes, we will bring in the complementary literature on housing hedonics, which builds on Rosen’s famous 1974 article in the JPE in 1974. • The Rosen article provides some more theory to think about as well as the framework used by most empirical work on the capitalization of public service and neighborhood amenities into house values. • I will also introduce a new approach to hedonics, that draws on the theory we have reviewed today. Preview

More Related