1 / 58

Bureaucracy versus Indians

Bureaucracy versus Indians. Chapter 5 AI_12_13. After Surrender. With defeat came political and bureaucratic control.

cianna
Download Presentation

Bureaucracy versus Indians

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Bureaucracy versus Indians Chapter 5 AI_12_13

  2. After Surrender • With defeat came political and bureaucratic control. • The rise of the standing army dramatically changed the interface between Indians and whites, but it was only the tip of the bureaucratic iceberg that came to dominate the lives of Indians.

  3. The Battlefield Moves to Washington • Once relegated to reservations, Indians struggled to adjust; it was either adapt or perish. • Many Indians died from white man's diseases and from starvation, but others adapted. • Familiar with owning and herd­ing horses, the Blackfeet began accumulating individually owned but communally herded cattle. • When the federal bureaucracy did fi­nally begin to try to control reservation life, "the tradition of individual ownership was so well established that Indians resisted government efforts to establish commonly owned herds from 1910 to 1920."

  4. Wards of the State • From an early date, Congress and the Supreme Court contended that tribes were to be treated as sovereigns, but Indians became wards of the state with politicians and bureaucrats in Washington, D.C., acting as their trustees. • Not surprisingly, the effect has not always been maximization of Indian welfare. • But it has surely meant the growth of the bureaucracy, as can be seen in Table 5.1.

  5. Bureaucratic Growth

  6. Battle over Property Rights Did Not End • Shifted from violent warfare to political competition • For much of the next century, the Indians lost these battles too • Property rights were altered due to the demands of politically powerful groups and the discretion of the large bureaucracy that emerged to implement federal Indian policy. • Institutional change was forced on the tribes.

  7. Adaptation • Even during the early years of allotment when the government was assigning parcels of land to individual Indians, "relative security of legal title created an opportunity for enterprising individuals to regain a limited degree of independence from the ration list.

  8. Institutional Change • Farming and ranching also gave ambitious men an opportunity to accumulate wealth outside the Bureau of Indian Affairs' patronage system and, through sharing and gifting, to establish themselves as autonomous leaders. • However, when the government imposed new institutions on the Indians, agricultural productivity suffered because politicization of the institutions exhibited a blatant disregard for existing and past cultural norms.

  9. Traditional Plains Indian Institutions • An open-ended meritocracy with many gently competing poles of authority. • Individual freedom was ensured by the representation of all families in council and by the requirement of consensus for national action. • Equally important was the nature of the economy, which rewarded coordination but did not make it necessary for survival. • Even the smallest family, functioning as a cooperative economic unit, could provide for itself under most circumstances.

  10. Traditional Plains Indian Government • Only in times of war or disaster were wider economic and security arrangements unavoidable. • Government therefore functioned "at need" rather than as a permanent, coercive establishment.

  11. Bureaucratic Dependence • But after relegation to reservations, government became both permanent and coercive. • "When we hear it said today that Indians do not believe in property or in private enterprise, we are still hearing the echoes of the struggle against Indian agrarian entrepreneurs in the 1930s—a struggle waged in the name of liberating landless Indians from poverty, but which in reality returned reservation economies to government dependence" (Barsh, 1987, p. 89).

  12. Understanding the Political and Bureaucratic Environment • Dominant Economic Theory of Government before 1970s: Government pursues the “public interest” • If markets fail, government can correct the problem • Government can replace markets (central planning, socialism) • Policies toward Indian reservations often have been experiments in socialism rather than capitalism.

  13. Public Choice and the Theory of Government Failure • Takes an economic approach to the analysis of government, pointing out that special interest problems can lead to government failure • Rejects the “public interest” theory of government • Public interest is a normative concept and each person’s subjective values determine their beliefs about what the public interest is.

  14. Property Rights as the Object of Interest Group Demand • Define the objects of interest group demand, and the functions of government law as: a) the assignment of property rights, and b) enforcement of each property rights assignment • Property rights convey the ability to benefit oneself or harm others and dictate the distribution of wealth • Changes in property rights reallocate, destroy, or create rents and therefore transfer wealth • Whenever an interest group is successful in altering the assignment of property rights, other individuals lose, so political competition is likely even if some groups are not seeking monetary or physically measurable wealth or rents

  15. Interest Groups • May pursue obvious self-interests • May pursue what members believe is in the public interest • Bruce Yandle, “Bootleggers and Baptists” • Individuals and groups pursuing their self-interests often can take advantage of the efforts of groups pursuing what they see as the public interests • Relatively small groups with large per capita stakes tend to dominate, due to information and organizing costs

  16. Costs of Organizing • Two relevant costs • the cost of arriving at an agreement, and • the cost of enforcing an agreement • Negotiation required to determine objectives and strategies • If everyone in a group (of any size) has interests in common, then they will act collectively to achieve them.

  17. The Logic of Collective Action • Large groups will face relatively high costs when attempting to organize for collective action while small groups will face relatively low costs. • Each individual member has incentives to avoid paying a full share (free ride). • Small groups may be effective while large groups may not be because it is easier to negotiate in and then police an interest group that is small.

  18. Special Interests • Government provides benefits for "special interests" who are able to influence the political process. • Government confers concentrated benefits to special interests, spreading the individual small costs across many consumers and taxpayers. • Individuals who have discretionary power in the political process (politicians, government employees) also pursue their own subjective values.

  19. White Farmers as Special Interests • The Dawes Act (also called General Allotment Act), adopted by Congress in 1887, authorized the President of the United States to survey Indian tribal land and divide it into allotments for individual Indians. • The act also provided that the government would purchase Indian land "excess" to that needed for allotment and open it up for settlement by non-Indians. • Bureaucracy responsible for procedures.

  20. Bureaucratic Preferences • Bureaucratic authorities can be viewed as firms producing a service or a set of services including enforcement of legislatively determined property rights assignments. • Exchange their services for a budget • Bureaucrats are utility maximizers with income and non-monetary perquisites (e.g., prestige, staff support, travel, leisure time or shirking, social and physical amenities, discretion to do the job) as arguments in utility functions. • Income and perquisites tend to be functions of both bureau output (i.e., the size of the bureau) and the discretionary budget

  21. Constraints on Bureaucrats • Mangers of enforcement bureaus prefer stricter enforcement of whatever restrictions exist than the legislature wants, and also try to inefficiently enforce rights in the sense of spending a larger budget per unit of enforcement than is necessary, if they can appropriate part of the budgets allocated by the legislature for their own benefit. • If there were no constraints on legislators' time and resources, they would force politically efficient behavior, but constraints do exist. • Legislators and interest groups monitor bureaus and use other control devises but control is "imperfect"

  22. Example • Lindsay (1976) recognizes that many bureaus produce numerous outputs, some of which are easily measurable and some of which are not. • Bureaucrat has incentives to produce the measurable outputs that correspond to the monitor's desires, while exploiting the uncertainty associated with unmeasurable outputs (e.g., to gain discretionary budget) • Veteran's Administration provides expected levels of easily measured outputs (hospital beds, patient days) but relatively low quality services for unmeasurable outputs • “If all dimensions cannot be monitored, then some power to scrimp on these attributes rest with those in the bureau, who can use the savings to forward their own interests"

  23. Eliminating Ethnic Communities • Carlson notes that "no student of property-rights literature … will be surprised that the complicated and heavily supervised property right that emerged from allotment led to inefficiencies, corruption, and losses for both Indians and society." • One of the major costs of transferring land to non-Indians may have been the reduced sense of an ethnic community on reservations. • McChesney calls this an "ethnic externality," meaning that outside customs and cultures made it harder to maintain tribal customs and culture.

  24. How to Explain the Dawes Act? • According to the special interest theory of politics, laws are passed because they confer benefits upon interest groups that are influential in the political arena. • In this case, the General Allotment Act formed the proverbial "iron triangle" of politics in which white settlers got the land, politicians received votes, and bureaucrats increased their budgets.

  25. texaspolitics.laits.utexas.edu/.../iron.html

  26. dopejam.com/bop/RUMBLING/POLITICS/triangle.html

  27. Public versus Private Interest • The guardianship model of Indian policy explains the relationship between the federal government and Indians as an effort by the government to correct imperfections in the institutional structure on Indian reservations. • Many reformers saw allotment as the only way to "Americanize" the Indian.

  28. Allotment (1887) • The dates when reservations were allotted varied considerably across Indian Country. • On some reservations, allotment ensued the first year after the Dawes Act, whereas on others allotment did not take place until after 1930. • Once allotted, the lands originally were to be held in trust by the federal government for 25 years, at the end of which time the Indian was to receive full fee simple title to the land.

  29. Leasing Allowed • During the period of trusteeship, the land was not to be sold, leased, or willed to another Indian or non-Indian. • But because many allotted lands were not coming into production, the act was amended in 1891 to permit leasing with the result that "leasing soon became more prevalent than working one's own plot on many reservations." • 112,000 acres out of 140,000 acres of allotted lands on the Omaha and Winnebago reservations were leased by 1898 (1984, p. 673). • The 1906 amendment to the General Allotment Act authorized the Secretary of Interior to issue fee patents immediately if any Indian was deemed "competent and capable of managing his or her affairs."

  30. Decline in Indian Land • When fee simple title to allotted lands or surplus lands passed to individuals, the land was no longer considered "Indian Land"—even if it was owned by an Indian. • The total amount of Indian land declined dramatically between 1871 and 1983 (see Table 5.2) as fee simple patents were issued by the federal government. • Measured in terms of privatization, the General Allotment Act was incredibly effective; measured in terms of Indian ownership, however, it was a disaster. • According to Washburn, "about 60 percent of this land passed out of Indian hands" (1971, p. 145).

  31. Special Interest Theory of Politics • Given that so many acres were transferred from Indian to white hands under this act, a special interest theory of politics provides an alternative to the "guardianship model" of allotment. • According to this theory, non-Indian special interest groups would seek legislation that would enable these groups to capture the wealth of reservations through political processes. • With reservations being established at precisely the time when western land values were rising, whites who were excluded from settling these reservations had an incentive to find a mechanism to obtain access.

  32. Demand for Legislation • The General Allotment Act allowed whites to purchase land from allottees or tribes or to homestead the surplus. • As a result, non-Indians ended up on the receiving end of "one of the largest real estate transfers in history." • If the white settlers were the demanders of this legislation, the politicians and bureaucrats were the suppliers.

  33. Policies for Votes • Given that Indians constituted a small portion of the population and that many Indians could not or did not vote anyway, congressional committees represented the interests of non-Indian constituents, and policy was catered to constituents. • If whites wanted access to Indian lands, they would expect their representatives to deliver the policies that would satisfy their demands for access. • The General Allotment Act did this.

  34. Bureaucratic Influence • If land-hungry settlers were the main beneficiaries of allotment policy, why weren't Indians granted outright title to the allotments so that white intrusion could occur faster? • Or why wasn't all reservation land declared surplus and opened to homesteading? • The answer centers around the desire of the bureaucracy to increase its budget.

  35. Bureaucrats as Policy Advocates • Bureaucrats are not only a government employee. • They are at the same time voters and as such employers of politicians. • Their pecuniary interests as employees probably dominate their interests as employers, as they get much more from the public funds than they contributes to them • This double relationship becomes more important as the people on the government's payroll increase. • Bureaucrat as voter is more eager to get a raise than to keep the budget balanced. • Therefore, bureaucrats are in a position to be "policy advocates" rather than simply policy implementers

  36. Bureaucratic Pursuit of Policy Changes • Bureaucratic institutional process tends to be dominated by individual bureaucrats pursuing their subjective goals by selectively seeking and implementing policy innovations. • Part of the general struggle for budgets, as well as competition for positions and promotions • “Propagate" their own policy agendas and have a relative advantage in interest group competition • Already organized, well informed about a narrowly focused political issues, generally can appropriate a portion of their discretionary budgets to cover some or all of their lobbying costs, and they have ready access to those who pass laws and set budgets

  37. Bureaucrats Create Uncertainty • Bureaucrats' power and discretion depend on the degree of uncertainty, and they often can increase uncertainty through "selective distortion” • Oversight sponsor faces the duel problem of determining both what the bureaus output should be from a political perspective, and how it should be produced, with the potential for bureaucrats misleading them on both counts. • Incentives to "educate" sponsors, by selectively informing them of the strength and wishes of other interest groups. • Therefore, interest groups press their demands to bureaucracies as well as (or instead of) to legislatures.

  38. Information and Misinformation • Bureaucrats have incentives to "educate" potential interest group allies and to "propagate" their agenda through "public information" or misinformation campaigns. • Strategies employed by bureaucrats include: • "(i) Alterations in the flows of in information or commands as these move through or across the hierarchical levels of the organization; • (ii) Variations in the quality or quantity of information leaked to the media, to other bureaus in the organization, to special interest groups, and/or to opposition parties and rival suppliers; and • (iii) Changes in the speed of implementation of policies as these are put into effect" (Breton and Wintrobe 1982)

  39. Bureaucratic Environment • Strategies and selective behavior in general are possible because of the way bureaucratic organizations and hierarchies work • Monitoring by superiors and sponsors is costly and the measurement of bureaucratic performance is generally difficult or impossible • Such strategies can increase monitoring costs and make measurement of performance even more difficult • Individuals who depend on a particular bureaucratic process for their livelihood have strong incentives to maintain it and prevent the implementation of competitive alternatives.

  40. Bureaucracy’s Expanding Role • By amending the Dawes Act in 1891 to allow for leasing allotments that had not been released from trusteeship, Congress allowed whites access to the lands while preserving an important role for the bureaucracy. • This gave Indian agents even more power, because it was up to them to determine and enforce the terms of leases. • "Leases came to be granted more and more freely, and by the turn of the century, the leasing of allotments was relatively common." (Carlson, 1981, p. 37).

  41. Hypotheses • From the special interest theory of allotment three hypotheses follow: 1. Congressional committee decisions will reflect the demands of constituents, and policies will change as these demands change. 2. Allotment would occur first in those areas where whites placed a higher value on the land held by Indians. 3. As the allotment process transferred millions of acres out of BIA control, the bureaucracy would have lost nearly all of its power had it not halted the process by retaining trust authority under the 1934 Indian Reorganization Act.

  42. Hypothesis 1 • Throughout the history of government policy regarding Indian property rights, those rights often have been ambiguous, leaving the assignment of those rights to bureaucratic discretion. • With Indian property rights not clearly specified, Congress and its agencies—such as the Bureau of Indian Affairs—have been in a position to redistribute the sticks in the bundle of rights to special interest constituencies.

  43. Cherokee Outlet • By not specifying exactly what rights the Cherokees had to their land in Oklahoma, Congress provided itself an opportunity to respond to changing constituent demands.

  44. Hypothesis 1 (cont’d) • The Cherokees, ranchers who grazed cattle in the outlet (CSLA), and the Boomers (people who wanted to farm the Outlet) competed for the right to use the Outlet. • Ultimately the Boomers won the battle as Congress passed an appropriation bill in 1889 authorizing payment of $1.25 per acre to the Cherokees, and in October 1889 the secretary of the interior ordered the CSLA to remove its cattle from the Outlet.

  45. Hypothesis 1 (cont’d) • The explanation for the Boomer victory is found in the relationship between constituents and their congressional representatives. • Though the ranchers were well organized, the Boomers were growing in numbers and by 1870 outnumbered cattlemen in every state bordering the Outlet. • The combination of larger numbers and higher land prices provided the necessary demand stimulus for changing the property rights to the Outlet.

  46. Hypothesis 2 • Just as the Boomers brought pressure to open the Cherokee Outlet for settlement, white farmers saw opportunity on Indian lands all over the West. • Throughout the 19th century, government land policy had made the public domain available at low prices to those willing to endure the hardships of frontier life. • With the Homestead Act beginning in the 1860s, people could obtain title to land by paying a small fee, generally $1.25 per acre, residing on the land for five years, and making improvements on the land. • With rising land values in the West, settlers had an interest in obtaining access to reservation lands.

  47. Dawes Act (1887) • The passage of the Dawes Act in 1887 provided the whites access to many, though not all, reservations. • Whether and when allotment began varied across reservations, but once the process began, non-Indians had access to Indian land. • Lands released from trusteeship could be bought and sold with clear title, and even prior to release they could be leased as a result of congressional action in 1891. • Moreover, if there were surplus lands after allotment, they were opened to homesteading by anyone.

  48. Hypothesis 2 (cont’d) • Since survey and administrative expenses made it costly for the Office of Indian Affairs to allot a reservation, those areas in highest demand by non-Indians should receive first attention. • Carlson finds that, as with the Cherokee Outlet, the data support the theory that Indian policy was heavily dominated by non-Indian interest groups.

  49. Carlson’s Test • The demand theory of allotment helps explain when allotment occurred. • "The more desirable a reservation was to outsiders, the more pressure they would have placed on the Office of Indian Affairs and the more likely that it would have been allotted sooner.“

More Related