1 / 11

Towards cooperative higher education

Towards cooperative higher education. Peter Somerville University of Lincoln 7 th May 2014. The case for reform. University governance is increasingly undemocratic and managerialised (Deem et al, 2008; Woods, 2011) – a problem of internal power

cirila
Download Presentation

Towards cooperative higher education

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Towards cooperative higher education Peter Somerville University of Lincoln 7th May 2014

  2. The case for reform • University governance is increasingly undemocratic and managerialised (Deem et al, 2008; Woods, 2011) – a problem of internal power • Academic labour is increasingly geared towards meeting more immediate economic needs of capital and the ‘market’ (Ciancanelli, 2007; Hill, 2009; Hussey and Smith, 2009; Molesworth et al, 2011; McGettigan, 2013; Brown, 2013) – a problem of purpose • Governments are increasingly interfering directly in how universities are run (Readings, 1996; Collini, 2011; Molesworth et al, 2011) – a problem of autonomy

  3. Interrogating the academy • Academic labour processes – teaching, research, administration, innovation, etc. • University employees operate within a variety of labour markets, in all of which people hire out their labour power in return for a wage or salary • Teaching is a distinctive kind of labour because its product (learning) is produced by students as well as by teachers – learners are both products and co-producers of education (Jones-Devitt and Samiei, 2011: 94) • Fee-paying students are customers (of the university as provider) rather than consumers (Barnett, 2011: 43-5) • It is often said that education is a public good (e.g. Collini, 2011) but it is not – it is a service provided to individuals by individuals • The means of production are broadly the same across universities, whether they are publicly or privately funded • Critics of recent changes in higher education tend to ignore the fact that academic labour is alreadycommodified, and also fail to notice the contradiction within the form of the education product, namely that it is beneficial both to individuals (as use-value) and to capital (as exchange value).

  4. Why cooperatives? • Cooperatives are democratically controlled and collectively owned organisations (Somerville, 2007; Woodin et al, 2010; Parnell, 2013) - UK universities are not! • Cooperation is not about volunteering or duty or even about solidarity, it’s about ritual and habit, which has to be learned as a skill or craft (Sennett, 2012). • Academic labour processes already involve a high degree of ‘cooperation’ (‘collegiality’ and ‘collaboration’), so cooperative governance is reasonable • Cooperatives decommodify labour power to the extent that the workers are their own employers and their remuneration is decided by the cooperative collectively • Such decommodification challenges both the capitalist wage form and managerial hierarchy • Cooperatives protect themselves against both state interference and the depredations of corporate capitalism, e.g. by means of an asset lock (against possible recommodification) – cooperatives as autonomous • The cooperative movement is a movement in abeyance (like the women’s movement - Taylor, 1989: 761)

  5. Cooperative education so far • The University of Mondragon – jointly owned by its academic and administrative staff, governed by a general assembly composed of 1/3 staff, 1/3 students and 1/3 outside supporters (mainly other coops in the Mondragon Corporation) (Matthews, 2013; Cook, 2013: 25) • BUT Mondragon is part of a social movement of Basque nationalism, different from the international coop movement • Cooperative trust schools and cooperative academies in UK (www.co-operativeschools.coop) – over 700 created over the last few years. In a cooperative trust school (or network of schools), the categories of member are staff, parents, pupils, and local community, all represented in a ‘forum’ that appoints trustees who appoint governors. In a cooperative academy, the school is sponsored by, e.g., the Cooperative Group. • BUT cooperative academies are like the Coop Bank, i.e. (loosely) controlled by the Cooperative Group but not by their members, and therefore not cooperatives at all; while in cooperative trust schools, the links between the membership and the running of the school are far too tenuous.

  6. ‘Trust Universities’ • Perhaps surprisingly, the idea of cooperative HE has been developed only recently… • Boden et al (2012) have proposed a trust model along the lines of the John Lewis Partnership: • Ownership would be clarified by placing each university’s assets in a non-revocable trust, which would hold the formal legal title to the organisation’s assets. This would also create clear governance responsibilities under trust law and prevent the privatisation of publicly funded assets. All current employees (academics and those in other roles) and students would be designated as trust beneficiaries, entitled to utilise university assets and resources… The trust deed, echoing that of JLP, would designate the purpose of the university as facilitating socially, culturally and economically beneficial scholarship, through the work of all employees and students, whether in research, teaching and learning, or public debate. This would affirm the university’s status as a community social asset and an element of the knowledge commons. By virtue of this legal strategy, Trust Universities would be beyond the predation of managers, markets or state interests. • (Boden et al, 2012: 21)

  7. Evaluation of the trust model • A trust has advantages over current HE governance: • protecting university autonomy • enshrining in law the social and civic purposes of universities (effectively, converting them into social enterprises) • mandating universities to act towards the benefit of all their employees and students • BUT a trust is not a cooperative: • A trust is not a membership body • University employees and students do not control the trustees and do not decide what is to their benefit • The employer/employee relationship form is retained (e.g. JLP’s ‘partnership’ is just window-dressing) • The concept of a trust derives from philanthropic traditions, not from the cooperative movement • Therefore this is ‘a sub-optimal model in comparison with a true co-operative’ (Cook, 2013: 36 – see further criticism in Cook, 2013, fn70: 36-37)

  8. The Mondragon model • All cooperatives must first identify the nature and composition of their membership • Research by Dan Cook (2013: 24) has shown that the most popular model is that of the University of Mondragon, namely 3 categories of member (staff, students and supporters) • However, Cook suggests that the representation of these categories should not be equal, and that staff should have greater representation than students, while the identity and position of supporters need to be clarified • Beyond a certain size of organisation (over 500 members) it may be necessary to form coops within the organisation, e.g. in Mondragon University each of its four faculties is a coop in its own right (Cook, 2013: 34)

  9. Comments on the Mondragon model • Clearly a member-owned, member-controlled organisation • Meets aspirations for workplace democracy • Shows that a strong federation of cooperatives may be necessary for a cooperative (university) to be viable (see Galor, 2008: 54) • Should (external) ‘supporters’ be ranked equally with (internal) staff and students? • Should students have the same degree of representation as workers?

  10. Conclusion • The purposes of higher education must include that of emancipation from capital-labour relations, and the cooperative form is a step towards this. • Moving forward requires a form of collective action in which the ‘collective’ is ‘a broad and distributed entity that includes those engaged in theory building alongside, and in collaboration with, participants in particular projects. And their “action” is viewed as having a performative force, surfacing tacit knowledge and bringing it to bear on what they [Gibson-Graham, 2006: 166] term “world changing experiments”.’ (Newman, 2013) • The formation of cooperative universities as such ‘collectives’ will have this performative force, taking us beyond the false dichotomies of capital versus labour, and private versus public, towards the transformation of capitalism into a society where wealth is not measured in terms of the cash nexus. • The cooperative movement remains in abeyance but the potential for collective action is there.

  11. Bibliography • Barnett, R. (2011) ‘The marketised university: defending the indefensible’, in Molesworthet al: 39-51. • Brown, R. (2013) Everything for Sale? The marketisation of UK higher education. London: Routledge. • Collini, S. (2011) What Are Universities For? Harmondsworth: Penguin. • Cook, D. (2013) Realising the Cooperative University. The Cooperative College. • Deem, R., Hillyard, S. and Reed, M. (2008) Knowledge, Higher Education and the New Managerialism: The changing management of UK universities. Oxford: Oxford University Press. • Galor, Z. (2008) Demutualization of Cooperatives: Reasons and perspectives. Available at: www.coopgalor.com. • Gibson-Graham, JK. (2006) A Postcapitalist Politics. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press. • Hussey, T. and Smith, P. (2009) The Trouble with Higher Education: A critical examination of our universities. • Jones-Devitt, S. and Samiei, C. (2011) ‘From Accrington Stanley to academia? The use of league tables and student surveys to determine “quality” in higher education’, in Molesworth et al: 86-100. • McGettigan, A. (2013) The Great University Gamble: Money, markets and the future of higher education. London: Pluto Press. • Matthews, D. (2013) ‘Inside a cooperative university’, Times Higher Education 29 August. • Molesworth, M., Scullion, R. and Nixon, E. (eds) (2011) The Marketisation of Higher Education and the Student as Consumer. London: Routledge. • Morpurgo, H. (2012) ‘Beyond solidarity’, New Internationalist July/August: 34. • Newman, J. (2013) ‘Performing new worlds? Policy, politics and creative labour in hard times’, Policy & Politics 41, 4: 515-32. • Readings, B. (1996) The University in Ruins. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. • Sennett, R. (2012) Together: The Rituals, Pleasures and Politics of Cooperation. • Somerville, P. (2007) ‘Cooperative identity’, Journal of Cooperative Studies 40, 1: 5-17. • Woodin, T., Crock, D. and Carpentier, V. (2010) Community and Mutual Ownership: A historical review. York: Joseph Rowntree Foundation. • Woods, P. (2011) Transforming Education Policy: Shaping a democratic future. Bristol: Policy Press.

More Related