1 / 31

Motivation

A Market-Based Framework for Bankruptcy Prediction Alexander S. Reisz Claudia Perlich Thursday, April 12, 2007 Third International Conference on Credit and Operational Risks HEC Montreal. Motivation.

arleen
Download Presentation

Motivation

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. A Market-Based Framework for Bankruptcy PredictionAlexander S. ReiszClaudia PerlichThursday, April 12, 2007Third International Conference on Credit and Operational RisksHEC Montreal Alexander Reisz

  2. Motivation • According to Black & Scholes (1973)/Merton (1974), the equity of a corporation can be seen as a standard call option written on the assets of the firm with strike equal to face value of debt • Put-Call parity: SH can also be seen as holding the firm and owing PV(F), but also having the (put) option to walk away, in effect selling the firm to BH for F, the face value of debt: C=V-PV(F)+P • BH are long the assets of the firm, but are short a call option; alternatively, they are long riskless debt, but short a put option: V-C=PV(F)-P Alexander Reisz

  3. The KMV Approach • From the pricing equation, and Ito’s lemma, , derive MVA (Vt) and σA • NB: F=CL+0.5*LTD • Compute a distance-to-default (DD), equal to • At this point, KMV departs from normality assumption and looks these DDs up in historical default tables • For more on the topic, www.moodyskmv.com Alexander Reisz

  4. Problems with the BSM Paradigm • 1) Shareholder-aligned managers would therefore maximize the volatility of the firm’s assets (new investments) • 2) which is positive for small d. Shareholder-aligned managers would therefore maximize the maturity of the firm’s debt • 3) Underestimates the probability of bankruptcy  overoptimistic credit rating

  5. Our framework • A (European) down-and-out barrier option is a contract that gives its holder the right, but not the obligation, to purchase an underlying asset at a prespecified price (strike) at a prespecified date (maturity), provided the underlying asset has not crossed a lower bound at any time before maturity V-DOC=PV(F)-P+DIC (the right to pull the plug) • Choosing very volatile projects raises the probability to end up in-the-money (and the extent to which you are in-the-money), but also the probability to cross the (exogenous) bankruptcy barrier; C/0 leads to an interior solution (you may even end up with a John and Brito (2002) problem) Alexander Reisz

  6. Alexander Reisz

  7. Alexander Reisz

  8. Alexander Reisz

  9. Results • Equity prices do reflect embedded barriers (on average, 30% of MVA) • Better performance of predicted default probabilities than in the BSM or KMV frameworks, both in terms of discriminatory power (ranking) and in terms of calibration • However, even in the barrier model, probabilities have to be recalibrated (no big deal); explains KMV’s modified strike price and departure from normality • But our power (ranking accuracy) is achieved without departing from the model’s assumptions! Alexander Reisz

  10. Results (contd.) • The Old Man ain’t dead yet: in one-year-ahead predictions, Altman (1968, 1993) scores outperform structural models! • Combine accounting-based scores and PD’s from structural models in a logistic regression to achieve highest power. Alexander Reisz

  11. Assumptions galore • Exogenous bankruptcy bound B • Markets are dynamically complete (existence of an MMA may not even be necessary) • No bankruptcy costs, APR holds (no rebate) • Constant interest rate Alexander Reisz

  12. Stock value (when F>B) with and • See it as a standard BS option minus the ex-ante costs of the covenant • Not increasing in  for all other parameters Alexander Reisz

  13. Brockman and Turtle (2003): a critique • When you assume that MVA=BVD+MVE, you force B>F. Indeed, the barriers backed out by BT can be fairly well replicated by just solving DOC(V,F,B)=V-F for reasonable parameters (Wong and Choi, 2005) • Although it is possible, it is suspicious when it holds for almost all firms (uniformly riskless corporate debt) • Good luck in front of a court of law (maybe it works in Germany…) • Contradicts KMV’s use of a strike price of CL+0.5*LTD<F; visitation and excursion times structural models; and Leland and Toft’s (1996) gamble for resurrection Alexander Reisz

  14. Backing out Vt, A, and B: a generalized market-based approach • Start with 60,110 firm-years (1988-2002) • Theory: A and B are constant for the life of the firm • Empirically: Allow A and B to vary from year to year for a given firm (amount of liabilities varies anyway from year to year; trivially allows for variation in leverage ratios) • However, force in a first step A and B to be constant over two consecutive years; the price and Ito equations for t-1 and t are solved for Vt-1, Vt, A and B • Keep Vt, A and B. Vt-1, A and B for time t-1 will be estimated from equations for t-1 and t-2 (so as to avoid a hindsight bias) • Left with 33,037 firm-years (5,784 unique firms) Alexander Reisz

  15. Summary statistics Alexander Reisz

  16. (Physical) probabilities of bankruptcy • Early bankruptcy: • Bankruptcy at maturity: Alexander Reisz

  17. Total probability of bankruptcy • First line: BS probability of assets ending up short of F, the promised repayment • Second line denotes the increase in the probability of bankruptcy due to the possibility of early passage (well…almost) • Allows one to stay within the model’s framework and fit B to a training sample Alexander Reisz

  18. Alexander Reisz

  19. Alexander Reisz

  20. Evaluating the performance of probability estimates • Accuracy does not reflect quality of probabilities: • No discrimination for extreme priors (a dumb model can achieve very high accuracy) • Equal penalty for prediction of 0.01 or 0.499 in case of default (although the latter is very large in credit risk): accuracy is not designed to judge continuous probabilities, but 0/1 predictions • But in credit risk, we are not interested in 0/1 predictions, but in a continuous variable (at what rate should we lend?) ; even more so the case because of asymmetry of costs (lending to Enron vs. denying credit to small businesses that would have deserved it) Alexander Reisz

  21. What we want • An evaluation metric that reflects how well a model ranks firms (discriminatory power) • Did our model predict a larger PD for firms that actually defaulted? • In particular, we want to know how many of the true defaults we catch for an arbitrary Type I error rate we are willing to tolerate • A metric that reflects whether the predicted PD’s correspond to ex-post frequencies of default (calibration) • Pb: you need many “similar” firms to judge ex-post whether your average PD over a given group corresponds to the ex post true frequency of default for that group • In general: recalibration is easy, more power is hard to achieve: favor the more powerful model Alexander Reisz

  22. Significant differences in AUC between DOC and BSM are identified by †, between DOC and KMV by ‡, and between DOC and the better of the two Altman scores by * (the symbol is entered next to the AUC of the dominating model). Alexander Reisz

  23. Alexander Reisz

  24. Need to recalibrate! Alexander Reisz

  25. Significant differences in AUC between DOC and BSM are identified by †, between DOC and KMV by ‡, and between DOC and the better of the two Altman scores by * (the symbol is entered next to the AUC of the dominating model). Alexander Reisz

  26. The picture KMV does not want you to seeFrom Saunders and Allen (2002) Alexander Reisz

  27. Significant differences in AUC between DOC and BSM are identified by †, between DOC and KMV by ‡, and between DOC and the better of the two Altman scores by * (the symbol is entered next to the AUC of the dominating model). Alexander Reisz

  28. Future research I: Fitting better models • Debt structures form a PF of American (outside; compound) barrier options • Debt covenants may specify that a certain time has to be spent consecutively (cumulatively) below the bankruptcy barrier (excursion (visitation) time): Parisian (Parasian) options • Allow for severity of excursion to play a role as well: Galai, Wiener, and Raviv (2005) • General problem: backing out a parameter when only numerical pricing is available Alexander Reisz

  29. Future research II: let’s be realistic • Force in a first step A and B to be constant over three consecutive years; the price and Ito equations for t-2, t-1 and t are solved for Vt-2, Vt-1, Vt, A, B and R, the option rebate • Provides a new estimate of violations of the APR rule on the shareholders’ side • Estimate bond prices using both early bankruptcy and bankruptcy at maturity; in both cases, LGD is given endogenously by the model • Alternatively, use the recalibrated total PD’s to estimate equilibrium bond yields on new issues. Alexander Reisz

  30. Alexander Reisz

  31. Alexander Reisz

More Related