1 / 28

HEDONIC ANALYSIS AS AN APPLICATION OF MULTIPLE REGRESSION

Austin Troy University of Vermont. HEDONIC ANALYSIS AS AN APPLICATION OF MULTIPLE REGRESSION. Valuing bundled goods. Being from France is not directly priced, but by comparing price of French and non-French wines can isolate that “premium.”

zorana
Download Presentation

HEDONIC ANALYSIS AS AN APPLICATION OF MULTIPLE REGRESSION

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Austin Troy University of Vermont HEDONIC ANALYSIS AS AN APPLICATION OF MULTIPLE REGRESSION

  2. Valuing bundled goods • Being from France is not directly priced, but by comparing price of French and non-French wines can isolate that “premium.” • The value of a 95+ mph split finger fastball (SFF) is not directly priced, but by comparing the contract trading price of a good SFF pitcher against one without, we can begin to price it • Except….

  3. Except… • What if those two pitchers are not otherwise identical? (ie the pitcher without the SFF happens to have several great breaking pitches (e.g. slider), he’s a better batter, a little older, and his ERA is a little lower • Now, in order to see how the SFF affects the contract price, we have to adjust for those other factors—hold them constant. • To make that comparison means we need enough pitchers to analyze such that we have sufficient variation across all those factors (a lot of other assumptions must be fulfilled, but we’ll get into that later)

  4. Now imagine a formula • Price = function of: • SFF (yes/no), • speed of SFF, • binary vector of other types of pitches (yes/no), • vector of average speeds for those pitches • Other stats (ERA, walks, strikes, age, etc.) • If I get an equation that relates 1-5 against Price with sufficient variability in the data set across attributes, I can then “control” for 3-5, and get an estimate of how 1 and 2 contribute to price. • That is, I “unbundled” the price of a major league pitcher to price something that is not directly price in the market

  5. Think of some other “bundled goods” Went a little crazy with the clip art • Cars • Food • Computers • Cell phones • Hotel rooms • Vacation packages • REAL ESTATE

  6. The housing bundle • This “price unbundling” most commonly is applied to real estate because • It’s technically feasible: • There are lots of housing transactions • There are many easily quantifiable attributes • There’s wide variation in housing attributes • It’s important • It’s the single most important asset class; is it being valued correctly? • Housing prices reflect so many non-market goods so it’s a great way to value amenities and disamenities

  7. Some parts of the housing bundle that can be valued: • # bedrooms/bathrooms • Square footage • Attached garage • Age of house • Building material • Luxuries: pool, hot tub, 100 ft tall lawn gnome • Property taxes • Size of lot  Proxy for value of raw land • However land value component can be further broken down because it derives from location and…

  8. …can also value things related to location: • “Quality” of neighborhood • You’re buying piece of the neighborhood • Often use proxies like income, crime, tenure, etc. • Municipal services • E.g. school district quality, availability of sewer/water/trash service, etc. • Site factors • Soil/slope constraints, views, climate, easements, hazards • Proximity and accessibility to: • Employment and services • Transportation (transit, highways, etc.) • Amenities and disamenities

  9. Hedonic analysis • Each component yields an “implicit” price, reflective of WTP for a marginal change in a given attribute • Price= fn(structure, neighborhood, location) • The result is a “schedule” of marginal prices for all the elements of home value • Can be used to create housing price indices

  10. Linearity • How does the relationship between price and attributes vary with magnitude of x and y? • One option is to transform independent variables. Here we log transform # rooms • So change in price now depends on number of rooms at which price is evaluated

  11. Functional form: dependent variable transformation • Linear model: 1 unit change in attribute results in  change in price; however, linear model is unrealistic • Semi-log model; take ln of price: interpret coefficients as % changes in y due to 1 unit increase in x; ie. Price effect depends on house price level at which evaluated • Log-log model: take ln of both sides: interpret coefficients as elasticities; % change in y due to % change in x; i.e. price effect depend both on level of y and of x variables • Box-Cox model: flexible functional form • Uses a power transformation • Ln, linear and sqrt are “special cases”

  12. Hedonic assumptions: • Single housing market: • All variability in housing prices accounted for • no omitted variable bias. • Proper functional form • No transaction costs • Unlimited “repackaging” of attributes • Independence of observations • Exogeneity • Price is dependent

  13. Sample hedonic studies of open space and forests • Tyrvainen (1997): urban forests in Joensuu, Finland—positive • Lutzenhizer and Netusil (2001) and Bolitzer and Netusil (2000): urban parks in Portland, OR—positive • Netusil (2005): urban parks in Portland OR—positive when the park is more than 200 feet from the property • Thompson, Hanna et al (2004): urban interface tree health and density in Tahoe Basin—positive • Nicholls and Crompton (2005): linear greenways in Austin, TX—positive effect when adjacent

  14. Sample hedonic studies of open space and forests • Acharya and Bennett(2001): % of open space up to 1 mile from a house in CT—positive • Des Rosier (2002): proportion of trees on property relative to surroundings in Quebec City—positive (scarcity effect) • Correllet al.(1978): greenbelts in Boulder, CO—positive • Morancho (2003): park proximity in Castellon; modest increase • Lacy (1990): open space in subdivisions in MA—positive • Espey and Owusu-Edusei (2001): urban parks in Greenville, SC—negative

  15. Example #1 A. Troy and J.M. Grove. 2008. Property Values, parks, and crime: a hedonic analysis in Baltimore, MD. Landscape and Urban Planning. 87:233-245.

  16. Methods • Regress property price for ~25,000 property sales in Baltimore against a range of control variables plus amenity and crime variables • 4 models: 1) ln (d2 park); 2) lin (d2 park); 3) Box Cox trans of price; 4) SAR model, ln(d2 park) = vector of untransformed control variables = vector of control variables to be log-transformed = distance to park = robbery rate for park area =interaction term for previous two =coefficient

  17. Variables • Models: • Log-log • Log-linear • Box-Cox • Spatial MAIN EFFECTS: • 1999 and 2005 robbery rates • Ln distance to nearest park (model 1); distance to nearest park (model 2) CONTROL VARIABLES: • Ln square footage of structure • Ln parcel area • Ln improvement value (assessed) • Bathrooms • Years old • Structure quality • Single family home (1/0) • Year transacted • Whether house is renter occupied (1/0) • Ln median HH income of BG • % HS graduates in BG • % owner occupied in BG • Median age of BG • Ln distance downtown • Distance interstate

  18. Defining and attributing parks • “Parks” under 2 ha and with less than 50% vegetated surface were removed to get rid of things like highway buffers, median strips, paved pocket parks and other park “fragments” with low amenity value

  19. Data acquisition: parks

  20. Data acquisition: parks

  21. Results R-squared of .66 Relatively low fit relates to problems with central city property data All control variables significant with expected sign Main effects are expected sign and significance Interaction is significant Almost no difference when using 1999 vs 2005 crime data

  22. Results: park & crime interaction • For lower crime levels, price increases with proximity to park, all else constant. • As crime rate increases, curve gets less steep • At a certain crime level, (~450% of national average) the curve reverses direction • Mean 2005 robbery index is 475% of national average for Baltimore

  23. Results: tree percentage • Above ~450% crime levels, property price decreases with proximity to parks • Gets steeper as crime rate increases • At mean crime rate for city (475%), parks are valued negatively!

  24. Model 2: linear versions Result basically the same, but get lines instead of asymptotic curves

  25. Classifying parks

  26. Hypothetical price effects

More Related