1 / 35

From impact evaluations to cost-benefit analysis?

From impact evaluations to cost-benefit analysis?. DEC Course Poverty and Inequality - Module 6: Evaluating the impacts of assigned programs March 28, 2008 Jed Friedman Development Research Group. Outline. Conceptual framework Challenge of accounting for ‘full’ benefits and costs

zev
Download Presentation

From impact evaluations to cost-benefit analysis?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. From impact evaluations to cost-benefit analysis? DEC Course Poverty and Inequality - Module 6: Evaluating the impacts of assigned programs March 28, 2008 Jed Friedman Development Research Group

  2. Outline • Conceptual framework • Challenge of accounting for ‘full’ benefits and costs • Evidence C/B education programs • Broader comparison across programs: C/B nutrition interventions

  3. Cost benefit analysis • Traditional cost-benefit analysis focuses on ‘efficiency’ arguments: determine the effect of a program φ on total output or income And compare it to its costs C(φ)

  4. Cost benefit analysis • Note that: • Distribution of program impact are irrelevant (costless lump-sum transfers/taxes) • Ignore problem of aggregation of individual valuation of the outcomes

  5. Cost benefit analysis • Generally ignore distributional aspects of policies (imp. for programs with redistributive objectives or with altruistic motivations) Initial position in the distribution does not matter • Social justice/positive political economy might be interested in: • Gains to specific groups of population at base state (ex. poor) • Proportion of people who gain relative to their base state • Proportion of people who reach an absolute level of outcome (ex. social values of merit goods, health and education)

  6. Cost benefit analysis • Full social costs of the program should include the welfare cost of raising funds, generally ignored.

  7. General framework • Consider a vector of policy variables φ, with social cost c(φ) • N1(φ) and N0(φ) is the number of people in each state {1, 0} • Assume constant relative prices • Total output: • Now consider a marginal change in φ. What is the corresponding change in output?

  8. Conceptual framework (1) persons induced to change state/sector: “entry effects” (2) change outcomes within state/sector (direct + indirect) (3) marginal social cost

  9. What does the conventional evaluation parameter measure? • Entry effects generally ignored • Indirect effects are also generally ignored (spillover/substitution, GE on prices) • Does not incorporate costs The conventional parameter ATT does not correspond to a marginal change and includes the gains accruing to participants…

  10. What does the conventional evaluation parameter measure? • Entry effects generally ignored (Moffitt 1992, 2003, Heckman 1992): • effect of the program on the rate at which individuals apply or gain admittance to the program. • Direct: policy changes the way applicants are handled • Indirect: policy reform changes the attractiveness of the program

  11. What does the conventional evaluation parameter measure? • Indirect effects are also generally ignored (spillover/substitution, GE on prices) • Program evaluations poorly designed to estimate the effect of system-wide structural reform which alters the entire environment.

  12. What does the conventional evaluation parameter measure? • However, evaluation parameter still informative under special conditions ..: • No GE effects, with partial participation • When benchmark/counterfactual state is ‘no program’ • .. about the “gross” gains from the existence of a program at a given level φ1relative to shutting it down (all or nothing) • Not appropriate for ‘fine tuning’/marginal changes, nor for economy-wide reforms → “Policy Relevant Treatment Parameters”

  13. Challenges in getting good estimates of benefits • Impact may accrue over the life-cycle • Place value on all relevant impacts • Pricing of impact might be distorted by market failures • Distinguishing between private and social costs (central for the efficiency motive for policies) • Selecting the appropriate discount rates to obtain the net present value of future stream of benefits

  14. Challenges in getting good estimates of costs • Account for true private and public cost, including distortions costs (and not nec. budget costs) • Assessing the cost when a project is scaled-up (marginal vs average in the presence of economies of scale). Reasonable to assume they are similar in the long run • Distinguish private vs public costs

  15. 1. C/B analysis of a voucher education program in Colombia • Vouchers for private secondary schooling in Colombia (PACES) – Angrist et al 2002 • Offered to low income families residing in poor neighborhoods and attending public schools • Value voucher: US$190 per year, ages 13-15, equal annual installments • average monthly fee for private schools US$340 • Average per pupil cost public secondary school slot US$350 • Assignment by lottery: natural policy experiment • Enrolment primary almost universal, enrollment in secondary 73% overall, 55% in poorest quintile

  16. 1. voucher education program:impact estimates • Randomized assignment → compare lottery winners/losers (OLS, OLS with controls) recover an intention-to-treat (ITT) parameter • Take-up: model scholarship use. • Lottery losers were awarded other scholarships: alternative financing (24%) • 90% lottery winners used the scholarship • Model selective compliance with 2SLS and recover the average treatment-on-the-treated (ATT) parameters

  17. 1. voucher education program:impact estimates • Lottery winners: • No effect on enrollment • 15% more likely to attend a private school • 0.12-0.16 additional grades completed (mainly due to reduced repetition (-5/6%)) • No effects on drop-out rates • 0.2SD higher test scores • 10% more likely to have completed 8th grade

  18. 1. C/B voucher program Estimated cost on hh’ld exp. • Total increase in hh’ld expenditures: • Increase in gross fees for winners $52 (greater likelihood of attending private school + spend voucher on more expensive private schools) • Increased opportunity cost: 1.2 fewer hours working, average h/wage 71c: 1.2x.71x48 weeks=$41 lost earnings • Lottery winners receive on average $74 more aid than losers extra net expenditure per lottery: 52+41-74=$19

  19. 1. C/B voucher program Estimated cost on gov. budget • Lottery winners receive on average $74 more aid than losers. • Reduced public schools costs: • lottery winners no difference in likelihood of attending school, but 0.14 less likely to attend public school $350*.14~$50 extra public expenditure per lottery: 74-50=$24

  20. 1. C/B voucher program Estimated total cost • Estimated public + private costs $19+$24=$43 per year • Administrative + distortionary costs assumed 30% increase in gov.expenditure • Costs incurred over three years

  21. 1. C/B voucher program Estimated gains • Gains to lottery winners: • 0.12-0.16 additional grades completed • 0.2SD higher test scores • 10% more likely to have completed 8th grade • Valuing gains (1): • Estimated return to 1 year schooling ~ 10%  program increases winner wages by 1.2% per year • Annual earnings parents $2,400 per worker (with lower education levels) ~ $3,000 • Annual benefits occur at ages 16-60

  22. 1. C/B voucher program • Net present value (Berhman, Knowles 2004): • discount rate is 3%, 5% or 10% per annum. • Benefits (of gains in grade completed) and costs over life-cycle discounted to age 13 • Benefit to cost ratios: • at 3% discount: 3.8 • at 5% discount: 2.7 • at 10% discount: 1.4 • Note: • Conservative: Adding gains from completing 8th grade + increased tests scores brings B/C ratio from 2.7 to 3.9 (at 5%) • Heavy discounting (benefits spread over large period)

  23. 2. C/B analysis ECD intervention in Bolivia • Daycare, nutritional and educational services 6-72 months old –poor urban areas Bolivia (Berhman, Cheng, Todd 2004) • Child care centers at women’s houses (training +loans/grants to upgrade homes) • Up to 15 children • Longitudinal information on participants + representative sample children same age group in program and non-program areas • Cross-sectional, matching, marginal PSM

  24. 2. C/B analysis ECD intervention in Bolivia: costs • Cost: estimated $43/month child enrolled (516/year) • Costs presented with/without 25% upward adjustment for distortionary costs of government financing • Costs calculating assuming that children take part to the program for 3 years (age 2-5)

  25. 2. C/B analysis ECD intervention in Bolivia: benefits • Benefit: use impact estimate of: • height gains (2%) • Shorten length time to complete education (1year) • Increase cognitive skills by 5% • to calculate long-life earnings via: • Increasing adult physical stature (1% increase height →2.4% increase wages (urban Brazil, Strauss Thomas 1997) • Increased number grades completed • Increased cognitive skills (conditional on grades completed) (1% increase cognitive skills →0.233% increase earnings, Alderman et al 1996)

  26. 2. C/B analysis ECD intervention in Bolivia • Implied benefit to cost ratio range from 1.7 to 3.7 • Largest contribution gains is increasing the number of grades completed

  27. 2. C/B analysis across programs:hunger and malnutrition in LDCs • Copenhagen Consensus 2004 • Objective MDG1: halving prevalence underweight rates by 2015 • Income alone insufficient: assuming a stable annual economic growth rate of 5%, growth would result in 0.5% yearly reduction in malnutrition • Not a single intervention: broad overview of different groups of interventions aiming at: • Reducing prevalence low birth weight • Infant and child nutrition and exclusive breastfeeding • Reducing the prevalence of micronutrient deficiencies (iron, vitamin A, iodine, zinc) • Investing in agriculture technology

  28. 3. C/B analysis hunger and malnutrition in LDCs • Attach a value to the benefit of averting 1 child from being LBW from not LBW • Ex. Adverse outcomes for low birth weight (LBW: birth weight<2.5 kg) • Excess mortality (40% more likely to die in the neonatal period) • Higher likelihood of being stunted • Cognitive and neurological impairment → lower earnings and productivity as adults • Higher vulnerability to diseases (infant and lifetime) • Intergenerational transmission (LBW more likely to give birth to LBW children)

  29. 3. hunger and malnutrition:Accounting for ‘full’ benefits • Ex. 1: Estimating benefits from reducing incidence of LBW on infant mortality • Do not attach value life saved • Study from Guatemala, India: risk neonatal mortality for LBW 4 times higher than 2-2.9kg, 10 times higher than 3-3.5kg • Value: $800 cost save life through measles immunization in early 1990s adjusted for inflation and distortionary taxation=$1,250 • Value to be adjusted for risk death for LBW gives estimated gain of about $93

  30. 3. hunger and malnutrition:Accounting for ‘full’ benefits • Ex. 2: Estimating benefits increased lifetime productivity through decreased stunting • UK long-term follow-up study estimates 1,000 gr less than normal birth →loss 0.5SD height (1.6 cm or 1% studies identical twins in the US) • 1% increase height →2-2.4% increase wages (urban Brazil) • Assumed annual earnings $500 a year in constant prices over a work life 15-60 years old • PDV at 5% discount rate of about $99

  31. 3. hunger and malnutrition:overview PDV different benefits

  32. 3. hunger and malnutrition:overview PDV different benefits

  33. 3. hunger and malnutrition:review various types of intervention • Overall benefit per LBW averted: 580-986$ • 60% benefits accounted for increased productivity • Review costs of different types of interventions addressing LBW (ex. treatment women with bacterial infections, treatment women with STD, drugs pregnant women with poor obstetrics history) • Calculate implied benefit to cost ratios ranges

  34. 3. hunger and malnutrition:

  35. Conclusions • Essential to account for full benefits and costs • Awareness of the assumptions underlying cost-benefit analysis and impact estimates • Parameter generally estimated in the evaluation literature do not lend themselves to marginal changes in policies • Recent literature on distributional treatment effects • Ex-ante simulations. And structural modeling

More Related