1 / 27

Are labour markets polarising?

Are labour markets polarising?. Craig Holmes. VML workshop on Skills Department of Business, Innovation and Skills, Sheffield July 23 rd 2010. Introduction. A person’s skills derive from a number of sources: Education (general skills)

ronda
Download Presentation

Are labour markets polarising?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Are labour markets polarising? Craig Holmes VML workshop on Skills Department of Business, Innovation and Skills, Sheffield July 23rd 2010

  2. Introduction • A person’s skills derive from a number of sources: • Education (general skills) • Experience (soft skills, informal learning, transferable skills) • Occupations (specific skills) • There are important interactions – education or experience grants access to certain occupations. • Different skills attract different returns in the labour market • These returns may vary along the wage distribution

  3. Introduction • Routinisation hypothesis (Autor, Levy and Murnane, 2003): • Price of computer capital has fallen since late 1970s • Computer capital replaces labour engaged in routine tasks • Non-routine tasks may be complementary to computer capital (e.g. management, skilled professionals) • Result: growth in non-routine occupations due to changes in demand (complementarities) and supply (displaced routine workers) • Polarisation hypothesis (Goos and Manning, 2007) • Routine occupations found in middle of income distribution • Non-routine occupations found at top and bottom of distribution • Managers, skilled professionals at the top • Non-routine ‘service’ occupations at the bottom e.g. hairdressers, cleaners

  4. Introduction • Change in employment share of wage deciles: Source: Holmes, (2010), SKOPE research paper no. 90

  5. Introduction • Similar evidence found for UK using NES (Goos and Manning), US (Autor, Katz and Kearney, 2006) and Germany (Spitz-Oener, 2006) • However, existing evidence relies on a strong assumption that average wages have remained constant. • If they have not, it is not clear what this evidence means for final wage distributions. • Also masks a lot of changing variation within occupations. • This paper looks to explain changes in wage distributions resulting from a range of explanatory factors.

  6. Wage distributions • Three changes: • Composition effect • Between-group effect – relative mean wages of different groups change. • Within-group effect – wages spread out due to new characteristics of groups. • In terms of the routinisation/polarisation hypothesis: • Workers move to high wage and low wage non-routine occupations (Goos and Manning) • Increased productivity of non-routine occupations raises relative wage (Autor, Katz and Kearney) • Some of new employees in non-routine occupations have different abilities to incumbents (Holmes and Mayhew)

  7. Wage distributions

  8. Wage distributions • Biggest issue with analysing changing distributions is separating out all effects: • Wage determination process: • yt = gt(x) • Composition effects come through changes to x • Level of education, occupational structure, union membership, demographics • Wage effects come through changes to g • Returns to education, occupational premia, union premia, returns to experience, discrimination • These may be different at different points in the wage distribution

  9. Data • Family Expenditure Survey • Household expenditure and income 1957-2001 • Two surveys for sample: 1987 and 2001 • Covers period of routinisation • Has wages and education attainment (unlike LFS and NES respectively) • Variables: • Age finished full-time education – convert this into dummies for degree, post-compulsory education and high school education • Experience, sex, union membership • No variables on racial background. • Not used at present: marital status, industry

  10. Data • The 1987 survey first to include data on occupation through socio-economic groups. • Broad groups; captures some of the pattern of routinisation

  11. Data • Creates larger occupational groups: • Seven groups • Corresponds to high skill non-routine, routine and low-skill non-routine occupations

  12. Data • Descriptive statistics (mean values):

  13. A quantile regression approach • Number of approaches to measuring changing distributions, usually involving some form of quantile regression: • Typical OLS regression computes mean values conditional on explanatory variables • Conditional quantile regressions compute quantiles of a distribution conditional on explanatory variables • However, we need to look at unconditional distributions • Firpo, Fortin and Lemieux (2007) – henceforth FFL – supply an appropriate methodology • Individual contribution of covariates to wage and composition effects • Similar to Blinder-Oaxaxa decomposition of the mean, but for all statistics

  14. A quantile regression approach • Data: • N observations, N0 from initial distribution, N1 from final distribution • Ti = 1 if from final distribution, i = 1,...,N. Pr(Ti) = p • Yi and Xi observed • Yi = Yi0 (1 – Ti) + Yi1 Ti where Yit = gt(Xi, ei), t = 0,1 • Data can be reweighted to find the (unobserved) counterfactual distribution. • Counterfactual is wage distribution that would have arisen given initial wage determination process but final explanatory variables

  15. A quantile regression approach • Reweighting: • where p(x) = Pr (T=1 | X = x) • Calculate p(x) using logistical regression • This counterfactual can be used to decompose wage and composition effects of a distributional statistic: • Give statistic represented by functional v(F) – e.g. percentile • Δv(F) = ΔvW + ΔvC

  16. Results: reweighting

  17. Results: reweighting

  18. Results: reweighting

  19. A quantile regression approach • FFL’s second contribution is to break wage and composition effects into individual components e.g. occupation, education etc. • Method found in final paper, omitted here for time. • Idea is to find a linear approximation of each statistic in each distribution using explanatory variables: • Composition effects are sum of change in composition of each explanatory variable, multiplied by wage return in initial distribution • Wage is sum of change in wage returns between counterfactual and final distribution, multiplied by final composition of each explanatory variable.

  20. Results: individual contributions • Decomposition by wage and composition

  21. Results: individual contributions • Large impact of declining unionisation at bottom and middle. • Increased female participation has a negative effect (through initial gender pay gap) and a positive effect (through a declining gender pay gap at bottom and middle. • Pay gap widening at the top. • Expansion of higher education has impact even on low wage jobs • Relative graduate premium increased at top and bottom, but not in middle

  22. Results: individual contributions • Small composition effect of occupational change at bottom • Correct signs, but tiny relative to unions and education variables • Larger effect of occupation composition at top esp. managers • Degrees important at top • Managerial jobs have become important in middle of final distribution – they were not in initial distribution. • Expansion of managerial class to middle and lower management • Relative wage of manual routine occupations increasing, rather than decreasing • Occupations in decline should have falling relative wages • Ability is important – those that stay are best at job

  23. Results: individual contributions • All percentiles had positive effects from increasing returns to experience – proxy for informal training and soft skills • These effects were largest at the top. • Hard to interpret changing constant term – contains wage effects for reference group as well as general ‘shift’ e.g minimum wage policies should push up wages at bottom. • The problem of selecting a reference group in decompositions is well known.

  24. Results: individual contributions

  25. Conclusion • There are effects on wage distribution from Goos and Manning’s polarisation effect • However, at the bottom end these are very small. • Occupational composition is just one factor explaining wage distribution changes • Education, experience and institutional factors play a role • In many cases, this role appears to be larger. • Little support for Autor, Katz and Kearney’s “polarisation of wages” effect • Antonczyk, DeLeire and Fitzenberger (2010): a US-only phenomena. • Evidence to suggest our within-group effect dominates

  26. Implications and further work • Understanding how the labour market is changing is important for a number of policy areas and goals • Inequality • Polarisation suggests a different explanation to rising inequality than SBTC or institutional explanations. • Social mobility • Declining routine occupations may alter traditional career paths • Do routine workers get trapped in declining occupations? • Skills policy • Are current skills sufficient for changing occupational structure? • Are skills already produced being utilised fully?

  27. Contact Details Craig Holmes ESRC Centre on Skills, Knowledge and Organisational Performance (SKOPE), Department of Education, Norham Gardens, Oxford Email: craig.holmes@education.ox.ac.uk

More Related