1 / 68

Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson

Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson. Patent Law 11.15.2011 Prof. Merges. Relief. Prospective Effect. Final injunction issues. Issuance. Preliminary injunction hearing. Complaint filed in District Court. Damages assessed for this period if marking (or actual notice).

orli
Download Presentation

Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Damages in One (Fairly) Easy Lesson Patent Law 11.15.2011 Prof. Merges

  2. Relief Prospective Effect Final injunction issues Issuance Preliminary injunction hearing Complaint filed in District Court Damages assessed for this period if marking (or actual notice)

  3. 35 U.S.C. § 284 “[T]he court shall award [the patentee] damages adequate to compensate for the infringement but in no event less than a reasonable royalty for the use made of the invention by the infringer.”

  4. 35 U.S.C. § 285 “The court in exceptional cases may award reasonable attorney fees to the prevailing party.”

  5. 35 U.S.C. § 287(a) Patentees ... making, offering for sale, or selling ... any patented article ... may give notice to the public that the same is patented, either by fixing thereon the word "patent" or the abbreviation "pat.", together with the number of the patent, or when, from the character of the article, this cannot be done, by fixing to it, or to the package wherein one or more of them is contained, a label containing a like notice. In the event of failure to so mark, no damages shall be recovered by the patentee in any action for infringement, except on proof that the infringer was notified of the infringement and continued to infringe thereafter, in which event damages may be recovered only for infringement occurring after such notice. Filing of an action for infringement shall constitute such notice.

  6. Damages • Two measures: • Actual damages: “Lost Profits” • Reasonable royalty • Actual damages & the problem of proof • Panduit Corp. v. Stahlin Bros. Fibre Works, Inc.

  7. Compensation principle • “But for” the defendant’s infringing sales, what would the patentee’s profits have been? • NOT a disgorgement remedy: patentee’s loss, NOT infringer’s gain

  8. Panduit Technology

  9. Holding Below • Special Master • 2.5% royalty on all sales by defendant Stahlin during the infringement period • 3/6/62  8/7/70 • Injunction too, of course

  10. Panduit’s damage claim • Lost Profits: Stahlin’s sales OR • Reasonable Royalty • Lost Profits on Panduit’s own sales • “Price erosion” profits

  11. Patentee Damages Theory • Monopoly price is the inventor’s reward • Competition lowers price; measure “harm from competition”

  12. Lost Profits • In 2-firm market, where infringer is second firm, may be easy to calculate • All sales of infringer would have been made by patentee • Always true?

  13. Panduit • What does the patentee have to show to prove it would have made sales actually made by infringer?

  14. 4-factor test • Demand for patented product • Absence of non-infringing substitutes • Manufacturing and marketing capability • Amount of profits that would have been made (accounting evidence)

  15. Panduit • What does the patentee have to show to prove it would have made sales actually made by infringer? • “Absence of acceptable noninfringing substitutes”

  16. Problem Here • Panduit factor 4, not 2 • Accounting method inadequate

  17. “DAMP” test • “Whether lost profits are legally compensable in a particular situation is a question of law that we review de novo.” Poly-Am., L.P. v. GSE Lining Tech., Inc., 383 F.3d 1303, 1311 (Fed. Cir. 2004)

  18. 1. Ability to manufacture “Normally, if the patentee is not selling a product, by definition there can be no lost profits.” Rite-Hite, 56 F.3d at 1548. The only exception is where the patentee has the ability to manufacture and market a product, but for some legitimate reason does not. Even in these situations, though, “the burden on a patentee who has not begun to manufacture the patented product is commensurately heavy.” Hebert v. Lisle Corp., 99 F.3d 1109, 1120 (Fed.Cir.1996).

  19. “[T]he record demonstrates that, despite his later success manufacturing and marketing a product, Wechsler lacked the capability to manufacture his device during the period of infringement.” Wechsler v. Macke Intern. Trade, Inc., 486 F.3d 1286, 1293 (Fed. Cir. 2007)

  20. Reasonable royalty: the fallback • Timing • Date infringement began • Hypothetical bargain procedure – Panduit a good example

  21. Reasonable royalty (cont’d) • Relevance of competitive situation facing firms • Including substitutes • In the background: cross-elasticity of demand

  22. Elasticity • How much demand would be lost from the patented product for every dollar increase in its price?

  23. Acceptable Substitutes • Two approaches to substitution: • Patentable = unique, therefore, no substitutes. • Antitrust approach, substitution is a function of cross-elasticity of demand. Therefore, there will usually be substitutes.

  24. Elasticity • If price rises by 10% - what happens to demand? • We know demand will fall • By more than 10%? • By less than 10%? • Elasticity measures the extent to which demand will change

  25. Price Elasticity of Demand • The responsiveness of demand to changes in price • Where % change in demand is greater than % change in price – demand is elastic • Where % change in demand is less than % change in price - inelastic

  26. Elasticity The Formula: % Change in Quantity Demanded ___________________________ PED = % Change in Price If answer is between 0 and -1: the relationship is inelastic If the answer is between -1 and - infinity: the relationship is elastic Note: PED has – sign in front of it; because as price rises demand falls and vice-versa (inverse relationship between price and demand)

  27. TotalRevenue If the firm decides to decrease price to (say) $ 3, the degree of price elasticity of the demand curve would determine the extent of the increase in demand and the change in total revenue. Elasticity Price $5 $3 D 100 140 Quantity Demanded

  28. The Fallback – Reasonable Royalties • “Hypothetical Bargain” principle • When? – Date infringement began • Factors • Do not reward infringement !! • Available noninfringing substitutes? • Does infringer get a profit?

  29. Principle/Goal of Patent Damages Doctrine Goal: find "the difference between [patentee’s] pecuniary condition after the infringement, and what his condition would have been if the infringement had not occurred." Yale Lock Mfg. Co. v. Sargent, 117 U.S. 536, 552.

  30. Goals/Principles II The question to be asked in determining damages is "how much had the Patent Holder and Licensee suffered by the infringement. And that question [is] primarily: had the Infringer not infringed, what would Patent Holder-Licensee have made?" Livesay Window Co. v. Livesay Industries, Inc., 51 F. 2d at 471.

  31. Numerous cases approach this from the patentee’s perspective • How much would the patentee have been able to charge in the absence of infringement? • How many units would it have sold?

  32. Growing Sophistication • Crystal Semiconductor Corp. v. Tritech Microelectronics Int'l, Inc., 246 F3rd 1336, 1356 (FC 2001) • "[T]o determine a patentee's market share, the record must accurately identify the market. This requires an analysis which excludes alternatives to the patented product with disparately different prices or significantly different characteristics."

  33. Grain Processing Corp. v. Am. Maize Products • Major step in development of balanced counterfactual infringement analysis • How would infringer respond to presence of valid patent in the market space?

  34. History matters! • Following trial on damages, the District Court, Easterbrook, Circuit Judge, sitting by designation, awarded patent holder reasonable royalty, 893 F.Supp. 1386, and holder appealed. The Court of Appeals, 108 F.3d 1392, remanded for reconsideration of lost profits issue. On remand, the District Court, Easterbrook, Circuit Judge, 979 F.Supp. 1233, again held that holder was not entitled to lost profit damages and awarded royalty instead.

  35. Grain Processing When basing alleged lost profits on lost sales, patent owner has an initial burden to show a reasonable probability that he would have made the asserted sales but for the infringement; once the patent owner establishes a reasonable probability of "but for" causation, the burden then shifts to the accused infringer to show that the patent owner's "but for" causation claim is unreasonable for some or all of the lost sales.

  36. Key holding Fact that competitor's product, as made by alternative, noninfringing process, was not sold on the market during period that patent was infringed by product as it was made by infringing processes did not render product as made by noninfringing process unavailable, for purpose of patent holder's claim for lost profits.

  37. Easterbrook: 979 F.Supp. 1233, 1236 • “A product that is within a firm's existing production abilities but not on the market--in this case, Lo-Dex 10 made by Process IV (see 893 F.Supp. at 1389-90)--effectively constrains the patent holder's profits. Potential competition can be as powerful as actual competition in constraining price. William J. Baumol, John C. Panzar & Robert D. Willig, Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure (1982).”

  38. Baumol, “Contestable Markets” Microtheory: Applications and Origins, 1986

  39. Grain Processing • 4 production processes; one (# 4) non-infringing • “Practically instantaneous” transition from infringing process to noninfringing one See why this is important? • Process 4 was not actually used . . .But it easily could have been!

  40. Lesson: • “There is nothing quite so useful as a good theory.” • !!

  41. Note dictum in the opinion • Patentees have “significant latitude to prove and recover lost profits for a wide variety of foreseeable economic effects of the infringement.”

  42. Examples • Rite Hite v. Kelly, 56 F.3d 1538, 1550 (Fed.Cir. 1998). • Infringer’s sale of “generation 1.0” model took sales away from patentee’s “generation 2.0” product; lost profits damages awarded even though patentee no longer selling generation 1.0 product

  43. Examples • American Seating Co. v. USSC Group, Inc.514 F.3d 1262, 1270 (Fed. Cir. 2008) “Although the evidence in this case was relatively sparse, it sufficed for the jury to assume that USSC offered the VPRo I for sale and then substituted the non-infringing VPRo II -- a bait-and-switch -- and to find that absent USSC's offer to sell the VPRo I, the sales would have gone to American Seating.”

  44. Entire Mkt value/ “convoyed” sales • Beatrice Foods Co. v. New England Printing and Lithographing Co., 899 F.2d 1171, 1175, 14 U.S.P.Q.2d 1020, 1023 (Fed. Cir. 1990): • Sales of products normally sold with patented product may be affected by infringement

  45. Lucent v. Microsoft • Reasonable royalty determination • One feature in complex product • Relevance of “entire market value” of overall complex product

  46. Basic Principles When a patent is for an improvement, and not for an entirely new machine or contrivance, the patentee must show in what particulars his improvement has added to the usefulness of the machine or contrivance. He must separate its results distinctly from those of the other parts, so that the benefits derived from it may be distinctly seen and appreciated.... -- Garretson v. Clark, 111 U.S. 120, 121 (1884

More Related