1 / 26

QR 24 Economics Review Session

QR 24 Economics Review Session. 12/3/2009. Agenda. Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures Moral hazard Adverse selection Net Present Value. Demand Curves. y-axis: price x-axis: quantity of (something) consumed Slope: usually negative

lawson
Download Presentation

QR 24 Economics Review Session

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009

  2. Agenda • Demand curves • Supply curves • Equilibrium • Market failures • Moral hazard • Adverse selection • Net Present Value

  3. Demand Curves • y-axis: price • x-axis: quantity of (something) consumed • Slope: usually negative • Why?  decreasing marginal benefits • Marginal benefit: if I already have 100 (or 1000, or 10,000) of something, how much would I get out of having 1 more?

  4. Demand Curve for Medical Care • An odd thing about demand equations is that they usually express quantity (x-axis) as a function of price (y-axis): • For example, Qd = 100 – 4P • This is the opposite of how you usually see this relationship expressed: y = a + bx Price $100 Demand $50 Quantity of medical care

  5. Demand Curves (cont.) • Health care example: Physician visits • Patient willing to pay a lot for that first visit • Perhaps the initial diagnosis is the most important piece of information needed • Patient willing to pay less for each additional visit • Perhaps 2nd, 3rd, 4th, …, opinions don’t add much new information • This is decreasing marginal benefits

  6. What Shapes Demand Curves? • Personal Income • For most goods, demand increases with income • People who make more money buy more stuff • Other prices • If substitute goods become cheaper, demand will decrease • During a sale at CVS’s in-store medical clinics, demand for routine care (e.g., vaccinations) would decrease at local doctors’ offices • Tastes/Need • People choose to spend their money in different ways • Sicker people demand more health care than healthier people

  7. sick healthy Medical Care Demand by Society Price $100 $50 Quantity of medical care

  8. Price-Responsiveness (Elasticity) • The responsiveness of the quantity demanded of a good or service to a change in its price • “Elastic demand” : |Ed|>1 • If the price goes up a little, demand goes down a lot • “Inelastic demand”: |Ed|<1 • If the price goes up a little, demand doesn’t change much

  9. sick healthy Price Elasticity of Demand Price Less elastic $100 More elastic *technical note: While elasticity is related to the slope of the demand curve, it is not exactly the same thing $50 Quantity of medical care

  10. Supply Curves • y-axis: price • x-axis: quantity of (something) produced • Slope: usually positive • Why?  higher prices give suppliers incentive to produce more • With constant marginal costs and perfect competition, supply curve is horizontal • Marginal cost: if we’re already making 100 (or 1000, or 10,000) of something, how much would it cost to make 1 more?

  11. Supply Curve for Medical Care Price Supply $100 Sample equation: Qs = 3P $50 Quantity of medical care

  12. Market Equilibrium • The price-quantity pair where the quantity demanded is equal to the quantity supplied • Set demand and supply equations equal (Qd = Qs) to solve for P, then plug in P to find Qd or Qs. • Represented by the intersection of the demand and supply curves • Economists call this the “optimal point” • Why?  It’s efficient since the value of the last unit consumed (marginal benefit) is equal to the cost of producing it (marginal cost) • Optimal points are usually noted with a “*”

  13. Market Equilibrium Price Supply $100 Demand $50 P* Q* Quantity of medical care

  14. First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics • If we assume • Rational individuals • Price-taking behavior (no monopolies) • Complete markets • Complete information • Then market exchange leads to a socially optimal (Pareto) outcome.

  15. Market Failures in Health • Incomplete information -> • adverse selection • moral hazard • The quantity consumed (and produced) is not efficient (i.e., is not at the “optimal point”) • Other market failures in health: • Consumers not well-informed • Consumers not rational • Monopolies

  16. Demand for Health Care • Demand for health differs from standard demand because (Grossman model, 1972) • Health not health care produces utility • Consumers can purchase health care or produce it through time inputs / behaviors / decisions • Demand for health care both raises utility (you feel better) and also can increase your ability to work, gain income, increase utility from additional consumption. • BUT… this model account for uncertainty in health outcomes.

  17. Demand for Insurance and Moral Hazard • The real world involves significant uncertainty • Insurance smoothes income shocks (raising overall utility), but produces moral hazard. • Optimal insurance: trade-off cost of moral hazard which induces unnecessary care with the welfare benefit of reduced uncertainty.

  18. Moral Hazard • Consumers who are insulated from risk behave differently than they would if they were exposed to full risks • Health insurance insulates patients from full financial risks • Good because we are risk averse • (So we’re willing to pay a “risk premium” for insurance) • Bad because of moral hazard

  19. Deadweight Loss • The loss of economic efficiency that occurs when the quantity consumed (and produced) is not optimal • When patients are insured, they face a lower price for any amount of medical care • Because they are insulated from the full price, they will consume more care (moral hazard)

  20. Moral Hazard Price Supply $100 Demand Quantity consumed (Qins) > Optimal quantity (Q*) $50 P* Pins Q* Qins Quantity of medical care

  21. Deadweight Loss Deadweight loss here = all the money that is spent on health care above what it is worth to patients (area of the yellow triangle) Price Supply $100 Demand Price received by providers PMD Providers are supplying more than they would at the efficient point, and patients are demanding more $50 P* Price faced by patients Pins Q* Qins Quantity of medical care

  22. Evidence for Moral Hazard • RAND Health Insurance Experiment: • Families enrolled over 3 or 5 years with levels of cost-sharing that vary 0%- 95%. • Spending at 25% cost-sharing at 81% of spending level with no cost-sharing and 69% with cost-sharing at 95%. • Estimated price elasticity of -0.2 • Little measured impact on health outcomes

  23. Adverse Selection • One of the two fundamental problems with the market for health insurance • Four conditions necessary for adverse selection: • Heterogeneity in health status of patients • Competing health plans • Premiums do not account for heterogeneity in health status of patients • KEY CONDITION: **Information asymmetry (insurers don’t know health status of patients)**

  24. Adverse Selection – Death Spiral • Sicker patients are attracted to the more generous plans • These plans will have to increase premiums to make up for the higher costs • Healthier individuals move out of generous plans because the premiums have increased • These plans will have to increase premiums again to make up for the higher costs…

  25. Adverse Selection • Potential solutions: • Single-payer • Risk-adjusted premiums • Reinsurance to compensate plans that experience higher-than expected usage

  26. Net Present Value • Asks how much a gain or a loss in the future is valued in today’s dollars. • Why? If I get $100 three years from now, this is equivalent to putting $x in the bank now and receiving interest on it. I only need to put x = 100 * (1 / (1 + r) )t in the bank (t = time, r = interest rate). • Discount factor: (1 / (1 + r) )t = (1/(1.03))^3 =.91 • If r = 0.03 and t = 3, then $x = 91.

More Related