1 / 20

What does market failure tell us about mission-oriented R&D?

What does market failure tell us about mission-oriented R&D?. David C. Mowery Haas School of Business U.C. Berkeley. outline. The market failure rationale. Mission R&D in OECD economies’ public R&D spending. Characteristics of mission R&D. A brief example: defense-related R&D.

haamid
Download Presentation

What does market failure tell us about mission-oriented R&D?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. What does market failure tell us about mission-oriented R&D? David C. Mowery Haas School of Business U.C. Berkeley

  2. outline • The market failure rationale. • Mission R&D in OECD economies’ public R&D spending. • Characteristics of mission R&D. • A brief example: defense-related R&D. • Some implications. • Conclusion.

  3. The market failure rationale • Common economic justification for public R&D investment. • Implies an allocation of R&D funding driven by magnitude of the private-social returns “wedge.” • Associated with a broader V. Bush (1945) “social contract” (Guston & Keniston, 1994): • Autonomy for scientists in setting R&D agenda: “Curiosity-driven” research. • Reliance on peer review. • But what share of public R&D investment is covered by this analytic framework?

  4. Mission-oriented R&D spending within the OECD • R&D investment to support gov’t agency programs. • Frascati: R&D spending classified by “socioeconomic objective” of funding agency. • Defense, space, agriculture, health, energy, industrial technology (categories based on funding-agency missions) account for at least 50%, and in most cases, >60%, of public R&D spending in 2003-2004 for South Korea, USA, UK, France, Canada, Japan, and Germany. • Spending on “advancement of knowledge,” arguably the category most closely connected with the “market failure” rationale, accounts for 25 - 30% of public R&D budgets in these economies.

  5. Characteristics of mission R&D • Mission R&D often combined with other policies (procurement) that enhance or offset the effects of funding for innovation. • In some cases (early US semiconductor IC development), procurement was more significant than R&D funding. • Complementary policy portfolio (regulation; healthcare delivery systems) varies considerably among mission agencies. • Major source of investment in R&D infrastructure (facilities, equipment, etc.) in many OECD economies (including US), and a large university-centered infrastructure in US. • WWII: UCB & Manhattan Project; MIT & the Rad Lab=> university FFRDC.. • Creation of US academic computer science research infrastructure supported by DoD investment during 1950s – 1970s. • Agency policy & personnel, rather than peer review, is central to policy and funding allocation in postwar US mission R&D programs. • Office of Naval Research; Agriculture Dept.; DARPA • Variation among mission R&D programs is nearly as great as contrast between mission and “advancement of knowledge” R&D programs. • Compare share of development, basic research in NIH, DoD, NSF R&D budgets. • Much of the direct “output” of mission R&D in fields such as defense, space, health, etc., is sold to gov’ts or in other “nonconventional” markets (healthcare: 3d-party payers). • Complicates measurement of pecuniary “spillovers” from innovation.

  6. The economic consequences of US defense R&D • Little consensus on the consequences of US defense R&D spending. • Through the 1980s, defense spending was portrayed by many critics as a drag on national competitiveness. • At least some of the IT-related technological pillars of the “New Economy” of the 1990s originated in defense R&D and procurement. • Growth of “entrepreneurial” US universities aided by defense-related R&D. Less of this is apparent in Europe. • Stern et al. (2000): comparative analysis of “national innovative capacity” doesn’t show strong benefits from defense-related R&D; Guellec & v. Pottelsberghe (2001) gov’t defense-related R&D investment has negative effects on measured TFP growth within OECD. • Effects of defense-related R&D differ considerably among sectors. • Contrast outcomes in IT, machine tools, nuclear power. • Scale and structure both matter. • Relatively open R&D system, diversity in defense suppliers and procurement, pluralism in defense-related R&D funding agencies may enhance civilian benefits. • But these structural advantages may be attainable only in the context of enormous scale. • What’s the counterfactual?

  7. Defense spending and IT innovation • Defense applications of IT-related industries => substantial federal involvement: • Pluralism: Support for R&D in industry, universities, gov’t labs. • Substantial procurement demand=> reduction in unit costs, penetration of new technologies into nonmilitary applications. • Federal influence on technology development was strongest in the early years of development. • Similarities between civil & defense-related demand; military procurement accounted for larger % of total demand. • Structure of defense R&D and procurement policy aided technology diffusion, entry, competition. • Procurement policy supported entry by new suppliers, especially in semiconductors. • Relatively weak IPR environment => substantial interfirm spillovers, limited market power in semiconductors, Internet through the 1980s. • Semiconductors, computer HW, SW all display declines in spillovers/spinoffs over time. • COBOL vs. ADA. • VHSIC program.

  8. Post-9/11 (& Iraq) defense R&D • Increased federal share of national R&D, largely attributable to growth in defense/homeland security share of federal R&D. • White House FY 2008 budget request cuts long-term DoD R&D. • Congress has reversed previous cuts, largely through earmarks. • Procurement (especially procurement of advanced systems) also likely to decline or remain flat. • “Homeland security” R&D dominated by biomedical research (~40% of $5 billion in FY ’08 “homeland security” R&D budget request). • Share of “black” programs within DoD R&D budget (20 – 22%) has not grown since 9/11.

  9. Some implications • Temptations and risks in applying “lessons” from mission R&D in one area to another: • “Evidence” of underutilization of DoD patents cited in support of Bayh-Dole Act of 1980. • Applying the “DARPA model” to US energy R&D (“ARPA – E”). • Using mission-agency R&D programs for broader objectives than those of agency mission (e.g., SBIR, Clinton Technology Reinvestment Program, DoE weapons-lab work for civilian technologies) has a mixed track record. • Emphasis in “Mode 2,” “Triple Helix” claims about “new forms of governance” seems overstated, given longstanding influence of mission agencies. • Many of the hallmarks of governance associated with the “Republic of Science,” e.g., peer review, have been less influential within mission R&D. • Inter-institutional collaboration, evaluation against objectives other than “contribution to knowledge,” have long history in mission R&D. • Ebb & flow of political popularity of different agency missions (defense, space, energy) has had major consequences for US public R&D investment portfolio. • Soaring biomedical R&D budget, flat/ declining budgets for physical sciences reflects shifting political fortunes of mission agency R&D budgets, despite importance of physical sciences in biomedical research advances. • Significant cross-national contrast in profiles of mission R&D among EU member states. • EU R&D funding accounts for ~ 5% of total member-state public R&D.

  10. Conclusion: Innovation policy & mission R&D • Rather than market failure, innovation systems approach is needed: • Sectoral & national systems matter a great deal. • Focus on structure of institutions and incentives within these institutions within mission-agency fields. • Caution is needed in applying “lessons” from one field of mission R&D to others. • Need to both broaden focus (recognize array of complementary policies) and narrow focus (on the sectoral/institutional specificities) in assessing mission programs. • From a policymaker perspective, the weakness of the greater richness & complexity of an “innovation systems” perspective may be its greater richness & complexity. • Coordination across fields, mission agencies, complementary policies within a mission-agency area is essential but difficult. • “GDP share” targets for gov’t R&D spending mean little without decisions on allocation among mission R&D agencies. • Sector-specificity is difficult to insert into a speech, onto an index card, or onto a slide. • But an indispensable starting point is recognizing that the market-failure analysis applies to a limited share (often less than 50%) of most nations’ “on-budget” R&D investment portfolios.

More Related