1 / 17

Ranking Games that have Competitiveness-based Strategies

Ranking Games that have Competitiveness-based Strategies. Leslie Goldberg, Paul Goldberg, Piotr Krysta and Carmine Ventre University of Liverpool. Ἐν ἀρχῇ ἦν ὁ ἀρρεψία Nash , καὶ ὁ ἀρρεψία Nash ἦν πρὸς τὸν οἰκονόμος.

freja
Download Presentation

Ranking Games that have Competitiveness-based Strategies

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Ranking Games that have Competitiveness-based Strategies Leslie Goldberg, Paul Goldberg, Piotr Krysta and Carmine Ventre University of Liverpool

  2. Ἐν ἀρχῇ ἦν ὁ ἀρρεψίαNash, καὶ ὁ ἀρρεψία Nash ἦν πρὸς τὸνοἰκονόμος... In the beginning was the Nash equilibrium, and the Nash equilibrium was with Economists…

  3. ... but then in the summer of 2005... • ...Daskalakis, Goldberg & Papadimitriou show that computing NEs is “hard” (in terms of PPAD) for graphical games • Later, [DP, Chen & Deng] show “hardness” for 3-player games and CD show “hardness” for 2-player games! • Q: Is NE a “meaningful” concept? • “If your laptop can't find it, neither can the market.” Kamal Jain. • A1: Define interesting classes of games (ie, describing the world) for which it is • A2: Compute efficiently approximate NEs

  4. Ἐν ἀρχῇ ἦν ὁ ἀρρεψίαNash, καὶ ὁ ἀρρεψία Nash ἦν πρὸς τὸνοἰκονόμος, καὶμπορεί ἀκμήνἐγγίωνἀρρεψίακαὶ / ήἀξιόλογοςἀστροθετέωτων ἄεθλος In the beginning was the Nash equilibrium, and the Nash equilibrium was with Economists, and it may still be for approximate equilibria and/or an interesting class of games

  5. Every morning in Africa... ... a Gazelle wakes up. It knows it must run faster than the fastest lion or it will be killed. Every morning a Lion wakes up. It knows it must outrun the slowest Gazelle or it will starve to death. It doesn't matter whether you are a Lion or a Gazelle... when the sun comes up, you'd better be running 0 mph 25 mph 50 mph 0 mph 25 mph 50 mph

  6. Ranking games A1: Define interesting classes of games (describing the world) for which NE is “meaningful”

  7. Ranking games describe the world but NE is not “meaningful” for them (ie, these games are “hard”). [Brandt, Fischer, Harrenstein & Shoham, 2009]

  8. Competitiveness-based ranking games return (speed) 0 mph 25 mph 50 mph Increasing effort 0 mph 25 mph cost (effort) Increasing effort 50 mph Aside note: Returns allow compact representation of these games

  9. Our algorithmic results A2 A1 A (F)PTAS computes an Ɛ-NE in time polynomial in the input (and 1/Ɛ)

  10. Games without ties • Return values are all different • E.g., no two players ranked first, Google page rank • Algorithm to find NEs of any 2-player such game 2 4 6 8 10 1 2 wins 3 5 7 1 wins 9 The support of a NE is a prefix of the strategies available to a player There is a polynomial number of possible supports It is well known that once having the support we can efficiently solve a 2-player game (essentially LP)

  11. Games without ties (further results) • Characterization of NEs for games with a single prize: “One player has expected payoff positive, all the others have expected payoff 0.” • Games without ties and single prize can be solved in polytime given the knowledge of the support • Reduction to polymatrix games [DP09] when prizes are linear (rank j has a prize a-jb) • Polymatrix games and thus linear-prize ranking games are solvable in polytime [DP09]

  12. Return-symmetric games (RSGs) • All players have n actions, all with the same return while cost-per-action is player specific • E.g., lion-gazelle game • Actions’ returns: all speeds in [0,50] mph • Effort for speed s is animal/player-dependant • NEs of these games can be studied wlog* for our class of ranking games r’ r’’ r’ r r’’ r’ r r’ r’’ r r’’ cost2(r) = cost2(r’’) r’ < r < r’’ * A game with O(1) actions can be reduced to a game with a polynomial number of actions

  13. PTAS for RSGs with O(1) players n 1 • Round down each cost (normalized to [0,1]) to the nearest integer multiple of Ɛ • Eliminate dominated strategies • Brute force search for an Ɛ-NE of the reduced game using discretized probability vectors (prob’s are integer multiple of δ)(in time (k+1)(#players/δ)) polytime Regret of 3Ɛ 1 0 1 n After step 2 each player has only k+1 strategies regret of Ɛ regret of 2Ɛ Ɛ=1/k, δ=Ɛ/(k+1) for k in N

  14. FPTAS for RSGs, O(1) players and single prize worth 1 1 j-1 j j+1 n win share j lose • Definitionof Ɛ-NE: • x’s are probabilitydistribution • 2.

  15. FPTAS: left-to-right … … is a collection of vectors of admissibile values that are multiple of Ɛ,e.g., Discard : sequences whose first 8 values are different than last 8 values of previous sequences

  16. FPTAS: right-to-left … Overall regret of Ɛ FPTAS … Output the x’s in = O(1/Ɛ9)

  17. Conclusions • Introduction of ranking games with competitiveness-based strategies • Interesting games (describing real life) • Encouraging initial positive results (wrt both A1, A2) • Work in progress: FPTAS works for many prizes • Open problems • What is the hardness of these games? • Related to the unknown hardness of anonymous games • Polytime algorithms for 2-player RSGs?

More Related