330 likes | 362 Views
This study delves into the why and who of prescription drug coverage, detailing the impact on individual finances and public resources. Discover the distributional and behavioral implications outlined in the talk, with insights from regression results and data analysis. Explore the nuanced dynamics of non-LTC and LTC insurance, predictors affecting payment responsibilities, and the influencing factors on OOP expenditures. Uncover the research methods, findings, and societal ramifications presented in this comprehensive examination of health care financial burdens.
E N D
Why all the Fuss about Prescription Drug Coverage?Out-of-Pocket Health Care Expenditures Edward C. Norton University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill
Acknowledgments • Hua Wang • National Center for Health Statistics • Sally C. Stearns • UNC at Chapel Hill • Funding from National Institute on Aging • R01-AG16600
Health Care Expenditures • Long literature in health economics • Predict health expenditures • At individual and national level • Focus is on total or public expenditures • Concern is with public finance and resources
Out-of-Pocket Expenditures • Little research on OOP expenditures • No one keeps track, hard to calculate • Important • For elderly Americans, OOP risk is high • Distributional consequences of public insurance • Affects economic behavior
Two Striking Graphs • First shows out-of-pocket health care expenditures by age • Second shows out-of-pocket health care expenditures as a fraction of income by age
Figure 1 • Mean OOP expenditures rise with age • $85 per month at age 66 • $485 per month at age 95 • Division between LTC and non-LTC • All increase is due to LTC • Young and old elderly face different risk • Different magnitude • Different composition
Figure 2 • What fraction spend at least half income on health care? • >10% at age 81 • >25% at age 90
Who and What? • Who faces the highest OOP expenditure risk? • What are the implications?
Outline of Talk • Medicare and Medicaid • Data • Regression Results • Implications • Distributional • Behavioral
Non-LTC Insurance • Inpatient, physician, pharmaceuticals • Medicare is fairly comprehensive • Many have Medigap policies • Medicaid for poorest 15% • Private for about 67%
Who Pays non-LTC? • Predictors • Health shocks, health status • Insurance (e.g., Medicaid pays for much of pharmaceuticals) • Some access issues (e.g., urban/rural) • Hypotheses • Low R-squared • Demographics should not predict well
LTC Insurance • Nursing homes (long-term and skilled) • Medicare provides minimal insurance • Medicaid is safety net • Deductible = wealth - $2000 • Co-payment = income - $30 • Little private insurance
Who Pays LTC? • Predictors • Health shocks, health status, disabilities • Substitutes: spouse, child • Ethnicity • Hypotheses • High R-squared • Demographics should predict well
Methods • Predict Pr($OOP/month > Threshold) • Non-LTC $100, $500 • LTC $100, $1000 • Control for age, sex, race and ethnicity, education, income, rural, marital status, year, census region
Other Methods • Threshold gets at most relevant variation • Two-part models: no action in first part for non-LTC, no action in second part for LTC • Looked at components of non-LTC (inpatient, physician, pharmaceuticals) • Looked at OOP/income
Data • Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey • 1992-1998 • Focus on aged 65 and older • ~10,000 people per year • Advantages • Linked to Medicare claims • Detailed diaries for all other expenditures
Data • Data on 24,636 unique people and 709,413 person months • OOP expenditures per month • Overall mean is $151 (highly skewed) • Mean of $70 for LTC • Mean of $28 for pharmaceuticals • Average age is 75 • 40% men, 89% white, 37% widowed • 13% Medicaid eligible
Regression Results • Hypotheses confirmed • Low R-squared for non-LTC (<.03) • High R-squared for LTC (>.26) • Age, sex, race, marital status all predict LTC extremely well, as expected
Implications: Distributional • Focus on the implications, not regressions • Distributional • Not much for non-LTC • Public LTC insurance incomplete, suboptimal • Spousal impoverishment
Implications: Behavioral • Behavioral • Savings over life cycle • Red herring, end-of-life expenditures • Changing longevity and savings • Flat-of-the curve medicine • Alternative motivation for exchange • Political economy
Distributional (1) • Not much consequence for non-LTC insurance • No one group seems greatly affected by OOP expenditures
Distributional (2) • Medicaid incomplete LTC insurance • Brown and Finkelstein (NBER 2004) • Medicaid structured in a way that discourages private insurance • Implicit tax • Elderly buy less LTC insurance than they want • Elderly have less consumption smoothing • This affects certain groups more: oldest-old, women, widows, whites, unmarried
Distributional (3) • Married persons pay less LTC • Perhaps spouse and child are substitutes • Or Medicare Catastrophic Coverage Act of 1988 works • Spousal impoverishment not repealed • More wealth and income protected if spouse • Lowers cost of nursing home care • As predicted, in MCBS, married persons have lower OOP payments conditional on NH entry
Behavioral (1) • Savings over life cycle • Hubbard, Skinner, Zeldes (1995) • Means-tested public insurance affects savings • Some will save less than otherwise • The longer you live, the higher the risk • Hard to balance precautionary savings, optimal consumption
Behavioral (2) • “Red Herring” literature • Importance of age in predicting end-of-life expenditures • There are two stories here, not one • Story for LTC expenditures is different • Age effect huge even after controlling for time until death (although endogenous) • Delicate relationship between disability, longevity, end-of-life, substitutes to NH
Behavioral (3) • Recent gains in longevity, especially for men • If unanticipated, then savings too low • Greater longevity means higher eventual OOP expenditures for many than anticipated
Behavioral (4) • Flat-of-the-curve medicine • Marginal benefits low, below average cost • This is more likely a problem for highly insured services, not LTC
Behavioral (5) • Literature on intergenerational transfers • If informal care is substitute (Van Houtven and Norton 2004) • If elderly parent has much wealth • May be reason to provide informal care, even if no exchange, only bequest, to preserve wealth
Behavioral (6) • Political science • Why did Congress pass the Medicare Modernization Act? • Focus on prescription drugs • Relatively little OOP on drugs • For young elderly bigger issue, they VOTE
Future Research • Other countries • Less economic research on long-term care in non-US countries than in US • Issues no less important • Hope that this conference, iHEA, better data sets, will lead to more research
Out-of-Pocket Expenditures • People respond to what hits their wallet • Expenditure risk high for LTC • Expenditure risk generally low for other • Many behavioral implications