1 / 35

Fully Distributed Costs and Two Part Tariff

Fully Distributed Costs and Two Part Tariff. Notes. FDC Pricing. Because Ramsey is difficult to implement must find alternative way to price for multiproduct firm Each output’s revenue covers its costs Must be able to separate out costs. Joint Costs. NARUC –

aelan
Download Presentation

Fully Distributed Costs and Two Part Tariff

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Fully Distributed Costs and Two Part Tariff Notes

  2. FDC Pricing • Because Ramsey is difficult to implement must find alternative way to price for multiproduct firm • Each output’s revenue covers its costs • Must be able to separate out costs

  3. Joint Costs • NARUC – • Joint costs “occur when the provision of one service is an automatic by-product of the production of another service • Example, • Gas well produces natural gas, propane, butane, and other gases. • The only possible manner of production creates a fixed ratio of the different product • There is no unique way of allocating costs to separate the products

  4. Common Costs • Products that cannot be produced simultaneously can incur common costs. • Example, • Petroleum refinery produces gasoline, diesel, heating oil from each barrel of crude oil. • The cost of the refinery depends on the amount produced of each of the products. • Yet, the proportion of each of the products may not be fixed. (i.e. more gasoline means less diesel produced) • Allocating common costs can be difficult

  5. Fully Distributed Cost Pricing • 1)relative output • 2)attributable output • 3)gross revenue • We can define these mathematically. • FDC requires each output to generate enough revenue to cover its attributed cost

  6. Attributed Cost Examples • Pizza Store • Breadsticks vs. pizza • Common costs = dough • Attributable costs = toppings • Railroad Company • Passenger vs. freight train • Common costs = track • Attributable costs = fuel • Electricity Utility • Residential vs. Industrial Consumers • Common costs = power-plant • Attributable costs = transmission and distribution

  7. FDC Pricing • How we split up the common costs depends on the method used. • Limitations • MC is not included => very likely inefficient • Cross-subsidization impossible to detect • P1<MC1 for product 1 implies subsidized by P2>MC2 • Encourages entry • Circular reasoning • Pricing depends on revenue, gross revenue determines pricings • Under-produce elastic goods

  8. Two-part Tariff • An attempt to promote efficiency and equity • Move to nonlinear prices • Uniform 2-part tariff • pq-+t • p is price per unit consumed • t is an access fee charged or license/entry fee, which allows a consumer to consume any positive amount • t=0 is linear pricing

  9. Examples • Electricity or natural gas • Flat monthly fee (access fee) • Pay per kilowatt hr (usage fee) • Pay per cubic foot of gas (usage fee) • Cell phones • Purchase cell phone (access fee) • Pay per minute used (usage fee)

  10. Declining Block Tariff • Marginal price paid decreases in steps as the quantity purchased increases • If the consumer purchases q • He pays • p1 * q +t, if 0<q≤q1 • p2 *(q- q1) + p1 * q1 +t, if q1< q ≤q2 • p3 *(q- q2) + p2 *(q2- q1) + p1 * q1 +t, if q2< q ≤q3 • If p1>p2>p3 => declining block tariff

  11. Non-uniform tariff • t varies across consumers • For example, • industrial customers face a lower t b/c they use a constant q level of electricity • Ladies night, where girls get in free • Discriminatory, challenge in court • Often used to meet some social objective rather than increase efficiency. • Initially used to distinguish between fixed costs and variable costs • View demand (Mwh) and peak demand separately (MW) • The two are connected and that must be accounted for

  12. Rationale • MC = P creates deficit, particularly if you don’t want to subsidize • Ramsey is difficult, especially if it creates entry

  13. Two-part Tariff Discussion • Lewis (1941) – decreases distortions caused by taxes • Coase(1946) – P=MC and t*s=deficit • Gabor(1955) – any pricing structure can be restructured to a 2-part tariff without loss of consumer surplus

  14. One Option • MC = P and fee= portion of tariff • Fee acts as a lump-sum tax • Non-linear because consumer pays more than marginal cost for inframarginal units. • Perfectly discriminating monopolist okay with first best because the firm extracts all C.S. • Charges lower price for each unit • The last unit P=MC • Similarly, welfare max regulator uses access fee to extract C.S.

  15. Tariff Size – bcef or aef P a b c P f e AC D MC Q Q

  16. Tariff not a Lump Sum • Not levied on everyone • Output level changes, if demand is sensitive to income change • Previous figure shows zero income effect • Demand probably changes when the fee changes

  17. Additional Problems • Marginal customer forced out because can’t afford access fee (fee > remaining C.S.) • Trade-off between access fee and price • Depend on • Price elasticity • Sensitivity of market participation • Access fee • price

  18. A digression on cost • Example of fixed costs • Wiring, transformers, meters • Pipes, meters • Access to phone lines, and switching units • Per consumer charge = access fee to cover deficit • We examine single-product • Identical to next model if MC of access =0 • Schmalensee (1981) modeled two different output, but one requires the other. • Some consumers can be priced out of the market • Results are the same for single-product model

  19. Two-part Tariff Definitions • Θ = consumer index • Example • ΘA = describes type A • ΘB = describes type B • f(Θ)=density function of consumers • The firm knows the distribution of consumers but not a particular consumer • s* is the number of Θ* type of consumer • š is the number of consumers

  20. Θ* Type Consumer • Demand • q(p,t,y(Θ*), Θ*) • Income • y(Θ*) • Indirect Utility Function • v(p,t,y(Θ*), Θ*) • ∂v/ ∂ Θ ≤0 • => Θ near 1 =consumer has small demand • => Θ near 0 =consumer has large demand • Assume Demand curves do not cross • => increase p or decrease t that do not cause marginal consumers to leave, then inframarginal consumers do not leave

  21. More Defintions • Let be a cutoff where some individuals exit the market at a given p, t • If , no one exits • Number of consumer under cutoff, • Total Output • Profit

  22. Welfare • w(θ) weight by marginal social value • Maximizing this equation ensures Pareto Optimality

  23. Constrained Maximization • max L=V+λπ • by choosing p, t, λ • FOCs

  24. where • Where is the change # of consumers caused by a change in p • and the marginal consumer receives zero surplus

  25. Utility FOC • Simplifies to • From the individual’s utility max • Where vy(θ) MU income for type θ.

  26. Income • Let vy=-vt because the access fee is equivalent to a reduction in income • Ignore income distribution and let • w(θ)=1/vy(θ) • Each consumer’s utility is weighted by the reciprocal of his MU of income • Substituting into Vp reveals

  27. Similarly

  28. Substitution Reveals • And let • From the FOC • Where • s=Qp+Q/s Qy • D= deficit

  29. Solving Gives • where

  30. Interpretation • Let • Marginal consumer’s demand (Roy’s Identity) • To keep utility unchanged, the dt/dp=-qˆ • Differentiate to get • Combining get

  31. Result 1 • If the marginal consumers are insensitive to changes in the access fee or price, that is, • then the welfare maximization is • P=MC • t=D/s • Applies when no consumers are driven away • i.e electricity • Not telephone, cable

  32. Result 2 • Suppose the marginal consumers are sensitive to price and access-fee changes • Then, the sign of p-MC is the same sign as Q/s-qˆ • And • p-MC≤0, then t=D/s>0 • if p>MC, then t≥0

  33. Deviations from MC pricing – Result 2 • Increase in price or fee will cause individuals to leave • Optimality may require raising p above MC in order to lower the fee, so more people stay • p>MC when Q/s>qˆ, because only then will there be enough revenue by the higher price to cover lowering the access fee.

  34. Deviations from MC pricing – Result 2 • p<MC and t>0 • Very few consumers enticed to market by lowering t • Consumers who do enter have flat demand with large quantities • A slightly lower price means more C.S. • Revenues lost to inframarginal consumers is not too great because Q/s<qˆ, • Lost revenues are recovered by increasing t without driving out too many consumers • Q/s-qˆ is a sufficient statistic for policy making

  35. Low Access Fees • Set low to get more customers • Positive externalities • Example, • Telephone company offers more people to call when there are more customers accessing their lines

More Related