1 / 35

Preferences

Preferences. Toby Walsh NICTA and UNSW www.cse.unsw.edu.au/~tw/teaching.html. Outline. May 5,15:00-17:00 Introduction, soft constraints May 6, 10:00-12:00 CP nets May 7, 15:00-18:00 Strategic games, CP-nets, and soft constraints Voting theory May 8, 15:00-18:00

niveditha
Download Presentation

Preferences

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Preferences Toby Walsh NICTA and UNSW www.cse.unsw.edu.au/~tw/teaching.html

  2. Outline • May 5,15:00-17:00 • Introduction, soft constraints • May 6, 10:00-12:00 • CP nets • May 7, 15:00-18:00 • Strategic games, CP-nets, and soft constraints • Voting theory • May 8, 15:00-18:00 • Manipulation, preference elicitation • May 9, 10:00-12:00 • Matching problems, stable marriage

  3. Motivation • Preferences are everywhere! • Alice prefers not to meet on Monday morning • Bob prefers bourbon to whisky • Carol likes beach vacations more than activity holidays …

  4. Major questions • Representing preferences • Soft CSPs, CP nets, … • Reasoning with preferences • What is the optimal outcome? Do I prefer A to B? How do we combine preferences from multiple agents? … • Eliciting preferences • Users don’t want to answer lots of questions! • Are users going to be truthful when revealing their preferences? • …

  5. Preference formalisms • Psychological relevance • Can it express your preferences? • Quantitative: I like wine twice as much as beer • Qualitative: I prefer wine to beer • Conditional: if we’re having meat, I prefer red wine to white • …

  6. Preference formalisms • Expressive power • What types of ordering over outcomes can it represent? • Total • Partial • Indifference • Incomplete • …

  7. Preference formalisms • Succinctness • How succinct is it compared to other formalisms? • Can it (compactly) represent all that another formalism can? • … • Complexity • How difficult is it to reason with? • What is the computationally complexity of ordering two choices? • What is the computationally complexity of finding the most preferred choice? • …

  8. Utilities • Map preferences onto a linear scale • Typically reals, naturals, … • Issues • Cardinal or ordinal utility? • Numbers meaningful or just ordering? • Different agents have different utility scales • Incomparability • Combinatorial domains • First course x Main dish x Sweet x Wine x …

  9. Ordering relation • I prefer A to B (written A > B) • Transitive or not: if A > B and B > C then is A > C? • Total or partial: is every pair ordered? • Strict or not: A > B or A ≥ B • … • Issues • Elicitation requires ranking O(m2) pairs • Combinatorial domains • …

  10. Case study: combinatorial auction • Auctioneer • Puts up number of items for sale • Agents • Submit bids for combinations of items • Winner determination • Decide which bids to accept • Two agents cannot get the same item • Maximize revenue!

  11. Case study: combinatorial auction • Why are bids not additive? • Complements • v(A & B) > v(A) + v(B) • Left shoe of no value without right shoe • Substitutes • v(A & B) < v(A) + v(B) • As you can only drive one car at a time, a second Ferrari is not worth as much as the first • Auction mechanism that simply assigns items in turn may be sub-optimal • How you value item depends on what you get later

  12. Case study: combinatorial auction • Winner determination problem • Deciding if there is a solution achieving a given revenue k (or more) • NP-complete in general • Even if each agent submits jut a single bid • And this bid has value 1

  13. Case study: combinatorial auction • Winner determination problem • Membership in NP • Polynomial certificate • Given allocation of goods, can compute revenue it generates

  14. Case study: combinatorial auction • Winner determination problem • NP-hard • Reduction from set packing • Given S, a collection of sets and a cardinality k, is there a subset of S of disjoint sets of size k? • Items in sets are goods for auction • One agent for each set in S, value 1 for goods in their set, 0 otherwise • One other agent who bids 0 for all goods

  15. Case study: combinatorial auction • Winner determination problem • NP-hard • One agent for each set in S, value 1 for goods in their set, 0 otherwise • One special agent who bids 0 for all goods • Allocation may not correspond to set packing • Agents may be allocated goods with 0 value (ie outside their desired set) • But can always move these goods over to special agent • Revenue equal to cardinality of the subset of S

  16. Case study: combinatorial auction • Winner determination problem • Tractable cases • Conflict graph: vertices = bids, edges = bids that cannot be accepted together • If conflict graph is tree, then winner determination takes polynomial time • Starting at leaves, accept bid if it is greater than best price achievable by best combination of its children

  17. Case study: combinatorial auction • Winner determination problem • Intractable cases • Integer programming • Heuristic search • States = accepted bids • Moves = accept/reject bid • Initial state = no bids accepted • Heuristics • Bid with high price & few goods • Bid that decomposes conflict graph

  18. Case study: combinatorial auction • Winner determination problem • Intractable cases • Integer programming • Heuristic search • States = accepted bids • Moves = accept/reject bid • Initial state = no bids accepted • Heuristics • Bid with high price & few goods • Bid that decomposes conflict graph

  19. Case study: combinatorial auction • Bidding languages • Used for agents to express their preferences over goods • If there are m goods, there are 2m possible bids • Many possibilities • Atomic bids • OR bids • XOR bids • OR* bids with dummy items • …

  20. Case study: combinatorial auction • Bidding languages: assumptions • Normalized • v({})=0 • Monotonic • v(A) ≤ v(B) iff A  B • Implies valuations are non-negative!

  21. Case study: combinatorial auction • Atomic bids • (B,p) • “I want set of items B for price p” • v(X) = p if X  B otherwise 0 • Note this valuation is monotonic • Very limited range of preferences expressible as atomic bids • Cannot express even simple additive valuations

  22. Case study: combinatorial auction • OR bids • Disjunction of atomic bids • (B1,p1) OR (B2,p2) • Value is max. sum of disjoint bundles • v(X) = max { v1(X1) + v2(X \ X1) | X1X} • Not complete • Can only express valuations without substitutes • v(X u Y) ≥ v(X) + v(Y) • Suppose you want just one item? • v(S) = max{ vj | j  S }

  23. Case study: combinatorial auction • XOR bids • Disjunction of atomic bids but only one is wanted • (B1,p1) XOR (B2,p2) • Value is max. of two possible valuations • v(X) = max {v1(X), v2(X)} • Complete • Can express any monotonic valuation • Just list out all the differently valued sets of goods • Hence XORs are more expressive than ORs

  24. Case study: combinatorial auction • XOR bids • Disjunction of atomic bids but only one is wanted • (B1,p1) XOR (B2,p2) • Additive valuation requires O(2k) XORs • But only O(k) Ors • Thus, XORs are more expressive but less succinct than ORs

  25. Case study: combinatorial auction • OR/XOR bids • Arbitrary combinations of ORs and XORs • Bid := (B,p) | Bid OR Bid | Bid XOR Bid • Recursively define semantics as before • B1 OR B2 • v(X) = max { v1(X1) + v2(X \ X1) | X1X} • B1 XOR B2 • v(X) = max { v1(X), v2(X) }

  26. Case study: combinatorial auction • Two special cases • OR of XOR • Bid := XorBid | XorBid OR XorBid • XorBid := (B,p) | (B,p) XOR XorBid • XOR of OR • Bid := OrBid | OrBid XOR OrBid • OrBid := (B,p) | (B,p) OR OrBid

  27. Case study: combinatorial auction • Downward sloping symmetric valuation • Items symmetric • Only their number, k matters • Diminishing returns • v(k)-v(k-1) ≥ v(k+1)-v(k) • Using OR of XOR, such a valuation over n items is O(n2) in size • Let pk = v(k)-v(k-1) • Then v(k) is • ({x1},p1) XOR .. XOR ({xn},p1) OR ({x1},p2) XOR .. XOR ({xn},p2) OR .. OR ({x1},pn) XOR .. XOR ({xn},pn)

  28. Case study: combinatorial auction • Downward sloping symmetric valuation • Items symmetric • Only their number, k matters • Diminishing returns • v(k)-v(k-1) ≥ v(k+1)-v(k) • Using XOR of ORs (or OR) such a valuation is exponential in size • Need to represent all subsets of size k • OR of XORs is exponentially more succinct than XOR of ORs

  29. Case study: combinatorial auction • Monochromatic valuations • n/2 red and n/2 blue items • Want as many of one colour as possible • v(X) = max {|X  Red|, |X  Blue|} • With such a valuation • XOR of ORs is O(n) in size • ({red1,p}) OR .. OR ({redn/2 },p) XOR ({blue1,p}) OR .. OR ({bluen/2,p})

  30. Case study: combinatorial auction • Monochromatic valuations • n/2 red and n/2 blue items • Want as many of one colour as possible • v(X) = max {|X  Red|, |X  Blue|} • With such a valuation • OR of XORs is O(2n/2) in size • Atomic bids in OR of XORs only need be monochromatic • Removing non-monochromatic atomic bids will not change valuation of a monochromatic allocation • Atomic bids need to have price equal to their cardinality • Anything higher or lower will only value a monochromatic allocation incorrectly

  31. Case study: combinatorial auction • Monochromatic valuations • n/2 red and n/2 blue items • Want as many of one colour as possible • v(X) = max {|X  Red|, |X  Blue|} • With such a valuation • OR of XORs is O(2n/2) in size • There can be only a single XOR • Suppose there are two (or more) XORs • There are two cases: • One XOR is just blue, other is just red But then monochromatic valuation is not possible • One XOR is blue and red But then again monochromatic valuation is not possible

  32. Case study: combinatorial auction • Monochromatic valuations • n/2 red and n/2 blue items • Want as many of one colour as possible • v(X) = max {|X  Red|, |X  Blue|} • With such a valuation • OR of XORs is O(2n/2) in size • There can be only a single XOR • This must contain all O(2n/2) blue and O(2n/2) red subsets • XOR of ORs and OR of XORs are incomparable in succinctness

  33. Case study: combinatorial auction • OR* bids • Can modify OR bids so they can simulate XOR bids • Recall that OR bids are not complete • But XOR bids can be exponentially more succinct • Get best of both worlds? • Introduce dummy items (which cannot be shared) to OR bids to make them simulate XOR • (B u {dummy},p1) OR (C u {dummy},p2) is equivalent to (B,p1) XOR (C,p2) • Since XOR bids are complete, so are OR* bids

  34. Case study: combinatorial auction • OR* bids • Any OR/XOR bid of size O(s) can be represented as an OR* bid of size O(s) • Homework exercise: prove this! • This bidding language still has limitations • Majority valuation requires exponential sized OR* bid • Any allocation of m/2 or more of the items has value 1 • Any smaller allocation has value 0 • No non-zero atomic bid in the OR* bid can have less than m/2 items • Otherwise we could accept this set and violate majority valuation • So we must have every nCn/2 possible subset of size n/2

  35. Conclusions • Wide variety of formalisms for representing preferences • Several dimensions along which to analyse them • Completeness • Succinctness • Complexity of reasoning • …

More Related