1 / 11

Empirical estimation of market power and firm conduct

Empirical estimation of market power and firm conduct. How can conjectural variation models help?. Alan Crawford and Benoît Durand OFT Seminar. The questions. Can we use conjectural variation models to measure empirically market power?

neola
Download Presentation

Empirical estimation of market power and firm conduct

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Empirical estimation of market power and firm conduct How can conjectural variation models help? • Alan Crawford and Benoît Durand • OFT Seminar

  2. The questions • Can we use conjectural variation models to • measure empirically market power? • identify the source of market power? Can we use conjectural variation models to tell whether market power is the result of product differentiation or collusion? • And if not, what else can we do?

  3. Empirical conjectural variations models and the conduct parameter • Goal: apply empirical conjectural variation models to measure market power and to draw inferences about firm conduct • Method: estimate a parameter, θ, (a.k.a the conduct parameter) • Value of θ measures market power, i.e. the wedge between price and marginal cost • The conjectural variations theory links some specific value of θ to firm behaviour

  4. Empirical conjectural variations models and the conduct parameter • BUT not all economists agree that empirical CV models allow us to draw inferences about firm behaviour... • If 5 firms compete in a market and θ = 0.5, what can we say about firm conduct? • If firms are not cooperating (Nash behaviour) θ = 1/5 = 0.2 < 0.5 • If firms are perfectly colluding θ = 1 > 0.5 • Does θ = 0.5 mean that firms are colluding? And if so, how bad is it? And how do firms sustain a collusive price level? • CV models do not provide an economic interpretation for what θ = 0.5 actually means. But how important is it to rationalise firm’s conduct beyond perfect competition, Nash and monopoly? • Objective: for ruling out perfect collusion or non-cooperative behaviour, empirical CV models might have a role to play (subject to practical issues that have to be overcome)

  5. Empirical evaluation of the conduct parameter: Calibration (EALI) • The conduct parameter is simply an Elasticity-Adjusted Lerner Index (EALI): • Pros: • Simple and quick to calculate ... BUT appearances can be deceiving... • Cons: • Measurement issues • Marginal cost is difficult to measure • Price-elasticity of aggregate demand must be estimated (or inferred) • Market shares depend on market definition • Injudicious implementation can lead to erroneous calibration • E.g. mixing wholesale margins with consumer demand price elasticities may be inappropriate • No statistical hypothesis testing • E.g. cannot test whether θ is different from 1 • No corresponding formula in differentiated product industries

  6. Empirical evaluation of the conduct parameter: CPM • The Conduct Parameter Method (CPM): use econometric techniques to estimate a structural model (supply relation and demand function) to recover the conduct parameter • Pros: • Modelling a supply relation involves making (explicit) assumptions about consumer demand, cost function, vertical relationships etc. • Estimate (economic) marginal cost • Perform statistical test to determine whether level of market power is different from that of important benchmarks (i.e. perfect competition, monopoly, etc) • Cons: • Can only be applied in homogenous product industries • For differentiated product industries, the approach is too demanding in terms of data (insurmountable obstacle in practice) • Model mis-specification may lead to biased measures • The shape of the demand and marginal cost functions may poorly approximate reality • The Corts’ Critique: the reality of the industry is poorly approximated by a CV model

  7. Are empirical CV models the only tool? • Empirical application of conjectural variation models considers that firm conduct can be measured or estimated • Critical issue: economic theory does not provide an interpretation for most values of θ • Alternative: why not compare a “menu” of economic models in which firms are assumed to behave in a certain way? • Question of interest: does market power result from collusion? • Compare one model in which firms are assumed to perfectly collude (monopoly) with a model in which firms are assumed not to cooperate (Nash) • Too simple? Firms may be behaving in ways so that they set price above the Nash level but below the monopoly level (but empirical CV models do not allow us to do much more) • This approach should allow the analyst to determine that part of market power that is due to product differentiation and/or multiple brand ownership (see Slade (2004) study of the UK brewing industry)

  8. The Menu Approach • Two-step approach: • Estimate a ‘menu’ of models that differ in the way firms are assumed to behave. • Select the model that best explains the data (different methods can be implemented; non-nesting hypothesis testing is one of them) • Pros • Modelling assumptions are clear • Flexible approach that can be applied to differentiated product industries • Hypothesis testing to determine which model (i.e. which firm conduct) is best supported by the data • Cons • Require specification of different plausible models. In differentiated product industries, this could mean “many models” → may be cumbersome to implement • Estimation of a demand model in differentiated product industries requires a large dataset and (often) making some simplifying assumptions about consumer pattern of substitution • Nagging feeling that the menu of models does not include an adequate approximation to the industry... .... BUT is it reasonable to suppose that investigations require the ‘true’ model?

  9. Concluding remarks • None of the methods is perfect (though some are less perfect than others) • When there is no clear cut evidence about collusion, Competition Authorities should consider relying on this type of empirical analysis (if they have no in-house economists just hire us!) • Obviously, implementation should follow best practice: • Model’s assumptions should fit the industry features • Perform sensitivity analysis • Contrast results with other type of evidence • Two methods to estimate the conduct parameter in homogenous product industries: calibrating EALI and CPM • Calibrating EALI maybe useful as a ‘quick check’ during the initial phase of an investigation but care must be taken about the quality and the relevance of the inputs! • CPM’s ability to formally test hypothesis against industry data may lead to conclude that some form of behaviour is not consistent with the industry • Menu approach is a viable alternative in both differentiated and homogenous product industries • Select the model (and thus firm conduct) that is most consistent with observed market outcomes but this method can be relied upon only during in-depth investigations

  10. Empirical illustrations • The conduct parameter method (CPM) • Genesove & Mullin (1989) study of the American Sugar Trust in the late XIXth century shows that the conduct parameter θ is close to zero. • The threat of European imports might explain the absence of market power? • The menu approach • Nevo (2000) study of the US ready-to-eat cereal industry reveals that firm margins are consistent with Nash-Bertrand • Comparison of predicted margin from different models (Nash-Bertrand, coordinated behaviour) with observed price-cost margin

  11. Locations and contact • London Brussels • The Connection Bastion Tower198 High Holborn Place du Champ de Mars 5 London WC1V 7BD B–1050 Brussels Telephone +44 20 7421 2410 Telephone: +32 2 792 0000 Email: london@rbbecon.comEmail: brussels@rbbecon.com • The Hague Melbourne • Lange Houtstraat 37-39 Rialto South Tower, Level 272511 CV  Den Haag 525 Collins StreetThe Netherlands Melbourne VIC 3000 Telephone: +31 70 302 3060 Telephone: +61 3 9935 2800Email: thehague@rbbecon.com Email: melbourne@rbbecon.com • Johannesburg • Augusta House, Inanda Greens54 Wierda Road WestSandton, 2196, JohannesburgTelephone: +27 11 783 1949Email: johannesburg@rbbecon.com

More Related