1 / 27

Chapter 17

Chapter 17. Monopoly. 1. Market Power. In many situations, competition is not intense A firm has market power when it can profitably charge a price that is above its marginal cost Most firms have some market power, though it may be very slight

martha
Download Presentation

Chapter 17

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 17 Monopoly 1

  2. Market Power • In many situations, competition is not intense • A firm has market power when it can profitably charge a price that is above its marginal cost • Most firms have some market power, though it may be very slight • Depends on whether their competitors’ products are close substitutes • Two market structures in which firms have market power: • A monopoly market has a single seller • An oligopoly market has a few, but not many, producers • Determining what is and is not a monopoly market can be trickier than simple definitions might suggest 3

  3. How Do Firms Become Monopolists? • Firms get to be monopolists in various ways: • Government grants a monopoly position to a firm (cable TV companies in local communities, drug patents) • Economies of scale (concrete supply in a small town) • Being first to produce a new product (iPod) • Owning all of an essential input (De Beers diamond producer) • Many of these ways of initially capturing market power tend to erode over time 4

  4. Figure 17.1: Scale Economies and Monopoly • Monopolist can make a profit because AC lies below the demand curve at some quantities • Two firms cannot make positive profits • AC lies above Dhalf for all quantities

  5. Monopoly Pricing • Monopolist will choose the price that maximizes its profit, given the demand for its product • Whenever the firm’s profit-maximizing sales quantity is positive, marginal revenue equals marginal cost at that sales quantity • Marginal cost curve applies as usual • Need to examine the shape of the marginal revenue curve • Recall that a firm’s marginal revenue curve captures the additional revenue it gets from the marginal units it sells, measured on a per-unit basis 6

  6. Marginal Revenue for a Monopolist • An increase in sales quantity (ΔQ) changes revenue in two ways • Firm sells ΔQ additional units of output, each at a price of P(Q), the output expansion effect • Firm also has to lower price as dictated by the demand curve; reduces revenue earned from the original (Q-ΔQ) units of output, the price reduction effect • The overall effect on marginal revenue is: • So the price reduction effect makes the monopolist’s marginal revenue less than price 7

  7. Figure 17.2: Marginal Revenue and Price

  8. Monopoly Profit Maximization • When a monopolist maximizes its profit by selling a positive amount, its marginal revenue must equal its marginal cost at that quantity • If marginal revenue exceeded marginal cost the firm would be better off selling more • If marginal revenue were less than marginal cost the firm would be better off selling less • Two-step procedure for finding the profit-maximizing sales quantity • Step 1: Quantity Rule • Identify positive sales quantities at which MR=MC • If more than one, find one with highest profit • Step 2: Shut-Down Rule • Check whether the quantity from Step 1 yields higher profit than shutting down 9

  9. Figure 17.4: Monopoly Profit Maximization

  10. Markup • A monopolist facing a downward sloping demand curve will set its price above marginal cost • Firm in a perfectly competitive market sets price equal to marginal cost, meaning that the firm has no market power • Extent to which price exceeds marginal cost is a measure of monopolist’s market power • A firm’s markup, price-cost margin, or Lerner index equals the difference between its price and its marginal cost, as a percentage of its price 11

  11. Markup • A monopolist’s markup at its profit-maximizing price always equals the reciprocal of the elasticity of demand, times negative one • The less elastic the demand curve, the greater the firm’s markup over its marginal cost • When demand is less elastic, raising the price is more attractive because fewer sales are lost • This also implies that demand must be elastic at the profit-maximizing price 12

  12. Welfare Effects ofMonopoly Pricing • By charging a price above marginal cost, the monopolist makes consumers worse off than under perfect competition • Consumers who buy the product pay more for it • Some who would have bought it under perfect competition will not buy it at the higher price • Welfare effects of monopoly pricing: • Firm gains • Consumers lose • Deadweight loss incurred • Deadweight loss from monopoly pricing is the amount by which aggregate surplus falls short of its maximum possible level, which is attained in a competitive market 13

  13. Figure 17.5: Welfare Effects of Monopoly Pricing

  14. Distinguishing Monopoly from Perfect Competition • Existence of more than one firm in a market does not guarantee perfect competition • How can we tell whether multiple firms in a market are behaving like price takers or colluding and acting like a monopoly? • Easy to answer if we could observe marginal costs and compare to price • Monopolists and perfectly competitive industries behave differently in responses to changes in demand and changes in costs 15

  15. Response to Changes in Demand • Monopolist’s profit-maximizing price depends on elasticity of demand • Price in perfectly competitive market depends on level of demand • If elasticity of demand changes but level of demand does not, provides a way to distinguish between market structures • Can investigate this through data collection over time and statistical analysis 16

  16. Figure 17.7: Response to a Change in Demand

  17. Response to Changes in Cost • How do monopolies and perfectly competitive markets differ in their response to changes in costs? • Consider the case of a marginal cost increase by a given amount at every level of output • Example: a specific tax, T, on firms • The pass-through rate is the increase in price that occurs in response to a small increase in marginal cost, measured per dollar of increase in marginal cost • In a competitive market, the pass-through rate is never greater than one (cannot increase P by more than T) • The monopolist’s pass-through rate depends on the shape of the demand curve • Can be greater than one with a constant-elasticity demand curve: 18

  18. P=(Ed / (Ed+1)) MC • or: PM is a multiple of its MC • if Ed=-2, then P=2MC 19

  19. Effects of a Specific Tax – Shifting the Supply Curve ST S Increase in Consumer Cost per Gallon Po + T B Pb T Price Paid by Consumers ($/gallon) A Po Ps = Pb - T Decrease in Firms’ Receipts per Gallon D QT Qo Gallons of Gas per Month

  20. Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Product Quality • Product quality is a decision firms make • Raising a product’s quality increases the consumer’s willingness to pay • Producing a higher-quality product usually costs more • The firm must decide whether the extra benefit is worth the extra cost • How does the quality provided by a monopolist compare to the level that would maximize aggregate surplus? • If different consumers value quality differently, the monopolist may not choose to offer the quality that maximizes aggregate surplus • May over- or under-produce quality 21

  21. Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Advertising • Spending on advertising is another important decision for many firms • Because the monopolist’s marginal cost is less than the price, each additional sale increases its profit • Firms in perfectly competitive markets have no individual incentive to advertise • Each firm perceives itself as capable of selling as much as its desires at the market price • Marginal benefit of advertising equals the increase in sales times the firm’s profit on additional sales • At the profit-maximizing level of advertising, this marginal benefit must equal the extra dollar expended • For a monopolist, the ratio of the amount spend on advertising to the firm’s total sales revenue, the advertising-sales ratio, equals the advertising elasticity divided by the elasticity of demand, times negative one 22

  22. Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Investments • Firms can also make investments in an effort to become a monopolist • Example: cable TV firms lobbying government officials to award them franchises • If firms compete to become a monopolist, they will spend up to the full monopoly profit less avoidable fixed costs • If spend on socially wasteful things (e.g., golf outings for local officials) the loss from monopoly may be larger than deadweight loss and include all monopoly profit • Rent seeking is socially useless effort devoted to securing a monopoly position • Welfare effects of monopoly need not always be so bad • Expenditures firms make to gain monopoly positions can be socially valuable (e.g., R&D spending in the search for patentable drugs) 23

  23. Monopsony • Read monopsony section: p:648-652 24

  24. Regulation of Monopolies • Deadweight loss from monopoly pricing provides a justification for government intervention • Government actions that keep prices closer to marginal cost can protect consumers and increase economic efficiency • Intervention can take many forms • Antitrust legislation (see Chapter 19) • Direct regulation of prices • Price regulation (not common in U.S. today) • More prevalent in the past • Still used for electricity, natural gas, local telephone service • More common in some other countries 25

  25. Why Are Some Monopolies Regulated? • Regulation arises out of political pressure and economic concern about market dominance • When governments create monopolies they may then regulate them to deal with the negative consequences • May create a monopoly to ensure that goods are produced at least cost • A market is a natural monopoly when a good is produced most economically through a single firm • Average cost falls as quantity increases • Second firm may enter but this would cause costs to rise • Government can designate one firm to be the provider • Institute price regulation to protect consumers 26

  26. Figure 17.11: A Natural Monopoly

  27. First-Best vs. Second-Best Price Regulation • Under regulation, ideally prices will be set at the competitive price • Price at which demand and supply curves intersect • Aggregate surplus will be maximized • First-best solution to problem of price regulation • Two problems with achieving this lead to second-best regulation • Regulator may not know the firm’s marginal costs • First-best solution would cause the monopolist to lose money • If P < AC • Best the regulator can do is set a price that makes aggregate surplus as large as possible, allow the firm to break even • Set P = AC 28

More Related