1 / 18

Advanced Microeconomics . 1 6

Advanced Microeconomics . 1 6. Mikołaj Czajkowski. Overview. Review Pareto optimality Positive representative consumer Normative representative consumer Utility possibility set Pareto frontier of the utility possibility set Linear social welfare function

Download Presentation

Advanced Microeconomics . 1 6

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Advanced Microeconomics .16 Mikołaj Czajkowski

  2. Overview • Review • Pareto optimality • Positive representative consumer • Normative representative consumer • Utility possibility set • Pareto frontier of the utility possibility set • Linear social welfare function • Social welfare maximization problem

  3. Pareto optimality • A feasible allocation is Pareto optimal(Pareto efficient) if there is no other allocation that Pareto dominates it • There is no feasible allocation such that: • No concern for distributional aspects

  4. A positive representative consumer • When can we treat the aggregate demand function as if it was generated by a fictional representative consumer? • A positive representative consumer exists if there is a rational preference relation such that the aggregate demand function is the Walrasian demand function generated by this preference relation • Fictional individual whose utility maximization problem when facing society’s budget set would generate the economy’s aggregate demand function

  5. A normative representative consumer • When can we treat the aggregate demand function as if it was generated by a fictional representative consumer and use his preferences as a measure of aggregate social welfare? • Normative representative consumer • Necessary condition – positive representative consumer exists • A (Bergson-Samuelson) social welfare function is a function that assigns a utility value to each possible vector of utility levels for the consumers in the economy • Function that expresses society’s judgements on how different distributions of individual utilities are compared

  6. A normative representative consumer • Using the social welfare function we may try to: • (redistribute wealth to maximize social welfare) • Value of this function would define social indirect utility function • The positive representative consumer is a normative representative consumer relative to social welfare function if so defined social indirect utility function exists • Positive vs. normative representative consumerpossible that the former exists and the latter not

  7. A normative representative consumer • If there is a normative representative consumer • His preferences have welfare significance • The aggregate demand function can be used to make welfare judgements • Always assuming optimally distributed level of wealth!

  8. Utility possibility set • – a family of (continuous) utility functions representing the preference relations of consumers • Attainable vectors of utility levels for the economy specified by is the utility possibility set:

  9. Utility possibility set • For two-consumer economy: • From the definition of Pareto optimality, the utility values of Pareto optimal allocation must belong to the boundary of the utility possibility set • Does the reverse hold? • Assume – the set is closed

  10. Pareto frontier utility possibility • Pareto frontier utility possibility: • It follows that: • A feasible allocation is Pareto optimum if and only if

  11. Pareto frontier utility possibility • Proof: If , then there is such that for all :and for some : . But only if there is a feasible allocation such that for all . Hence Pareto dominates . Conversely, if is not a Pareto optimum, then it is Pareto dominated by some feasible , which means that for all and for some . Hence .

  12. Pareto frontier utility possibility • If every and every is convex, and if the utility functions are concave, then the utility possibility set is convex.

  13. Linear social welfare function • Assume society’s distributional principles can be summarized in a social welfare functionassigning social utility values to the various possible vectors of utilities for the consumers, and is linear: • For we have • because social welfare nondecreasing in the consumer’s utility levels

  14. Social welfare maximization problem • Which points in the utility possibility set maximize our measure of social welfare?

  15. Social welfare maximization problem • If is a solution to SWMP with , then • (i.e. is the utility vector of a Pareto optimal allocation) • Every linear social welfare optimum with weights is Pareto optimal • If is convex, then for any , there is , , such that for all : • (i.e. is a solution to the SWMP) • Every Pareto optimal allocation (and hence, every Walrasian equilibrium) is a social welfare optimum for some welfare weights • If is not convex is every Pareto optimum still a maximum of SWMP?

  16. Social welfare maximization problem • Using the social welfare weights associated with a particular Pareto optimal allocation (e.g. Walrasian equilibrium) is equivalent to the case of the welfare optimum in a single-consumer, single-firm economy • Utility function of a normative consumer: • Let be the aggregate production set • Pair is a solution to the problem:

  17. Social welfare maximization problem

  18. Literature • Readings: • MC: 16E • V:17.9

More Related