1 / 33

Credit to slides by Carmine Ventre (part of cogestion game slide)

Congestion Games (Review and more definitions), Potential Games, Network Congestion games, Total Search Problems, PPAD, PLS completeness, easy congestion problems, hard congestion problems. Credit to slides by Carmine Ventre (part of cogestion game slide)

baylee
Download Presentation

Credit to slides by Carmine Ventre (part of cogestion game slide)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Congestion Games (Review and more definitions), Potential Games, Network Congestion games, Total Search Problems, PPAD, PLS completeness, easy congestion problems, hard congestion problems Credit to slides by Carmine Ventre (part of cogestion game slide) Added/modified by Michal Feldman and Amos Fiat

  2. (General) Congestion Games • resources • roads 1,2,3,4 • players • driver A, driver B • strategies: which roads I use for reach my destination? • A wants to go in Salerno • e.g. SA={{1,2},{3,4}} • B wants to go in Napoli • e.g. SB={{1,4},{2,3}} • what about the payoffs? A B Roma Milano road 1 road 4 road 2 road 3 Napoli Salerno

  3. Payoffs in (G)CG: an example A SIRF (Small Index Road First) B • A choose path 1,2 • B choose path 1,4 • uA = - (c1(2) + c2(1)) = - 4 • uB = - (c1(2) + c4(1)) = - 5 Roma Milano road 1 road 4 road 2 road 3 Napoli Salerno B Costs for the roads {1,4} {2,3} c1(1)=2 c1(2)= 3 c2(1)=1 c2(2)= 4 c3(1)=4 c3(2)= 6 c4(1)=2 c4(2)= 5 {1,2} A {3,4}

  4. Congestion games: special cases • Symmetric CG • Si are all the same and payoffs are identical symmetric function of n-1 variables • Network CG • Each player has a starting and terminal node and the strategies are the paths in the network

  5. Rosenthal’s result • The class of GCG is “nice” • A pure Nash equilibrium exists • Introduces the potential function:

  6. Potential functions Several kind of potential functions: • Ordinal potential function • Weighted potential function • (Exact) potential function • Generalized ordinal potential function

  7. Ordinal potential function • A function P (from S to R) is an OPF for a game G if for every player i • ui(s-i, x) - ui(s-i, z) > 0 iff P(s-i, x) - P(s-i, z) > 0 • for every x, z in Si and for every s-i BoS = P1 = u1(B,B) – u1(S,B) > 0 implies that P1(B,B) – P1(S,B) > 0 u1(B,S) – u1(S,S) < 0 implies that P1(B,S) – P1(S,S) < 0 P1(B,B) – P1(S,B) > 0 implies that u1(B,B) – u1(S,B) > 0 and that u2(B,B) – u2(S,B) > 0 P1 is an ordinal potential function for BoS game

  8. A B (3,1) (4,0) 11 9 A P3 = G’ = (2,4) (1,0) 8 0 B u1(A,A) – u1(B,A) = 3 - 2 = 1/3 (P3(A,A) – P3(B,A)) P3 is a (1/3,1/2)-potential function for the game G’ u1(A,B) – u1(B,B) = 4 - 1 = 1/3 (P3(A,B) – P3(B,B)) u2(B,A) – u2(B,B) = 4 - 0 = 1/2 (P3(B,A) – P3(B,B)) u2(A,A) – u2(A,B) = 1 - 0 = 1/2 (P3(A,A) – P3(A,B)) Weighted potential function • A function P (from S to R) is a w-PF for a game G if for every player i • ui(s-i, x) - ui(s-i, z) = wi (P(s-i, x) - P(s-i, z)) • for every x, z in Si and for every s-i C D C P2 = PD = D u1(C,C) – u1(D,C) = 1 = 2 (P2(C,C) – P2(D,C)) u1(C,D) – u1(D,D) = 3 = 2 (P2(C,D) – P2(D,D)) P2 is a (2,2)-potential function for PD game u2(D,C) – u2(D,D) = 3 = 2 (P2(D,C) – P2(D,D)) u2(C,C) – u2(C,D) = 1 = 2 (P2(C,C) – P2(C,D))

  9. Weighted potential function m identical machines, n jobs, and {wi}i=1..n the weights of the jobs Jobs seek to minimize the makespan on their machine, Take If job i moves from machine j to j’, then the difference in load is and the difference in the potential function is

  10. Weighted potential function (example) m identical machines, {wi}i=1..n job weights If job i moves from machine j to j’, then the difference in load is

  11. Ordinal potential function (example) m machines, {wij}i=1..n,j=1..m job weights wij – weight of job i on machine j If job i moves from machine j to j’, then the difference in load is

  12. (Exact) potential function A function P (from S to R) is an (exact) PF for a game G if it is a w-potential function for G with wi = 1 for every i C D C P4 = PD = D u1(C,C) – u1(D,C) = P4(C,C) – P4(D,C) u1(C,D) – u1(D,D) = P4(C,D) – P4(D,D) P4 is a potential function for PD game u2(D,C) – u2(D,D) = P4(D,C) – P4(D,D) u2(C,C) – u2(C,D) = P4(C,C) – P4(C,D)

  13. Generalized ordinal potential function A function P (from S to R) is an GOPF for a game G if for every player i ui(s-i, x) - ui(s-i, z) > 0 implies P(s-i, x) - P(s-i, z) > 0 for every x, z in Si and for every s-i in S-i A B A G’’ = P5 = B P5 is a generalized ordinal potential function for the game G’’ P5 is not an ordinal potential function for the game G’’ P5(A,B) – P5(A,A) > 0 implies that u1(A,B) – u1(A,A) > 0 but not that u2(A,B) – u2(A,A) > 0

  14. Potential games • A game that admits an OPF is called an ordinal potential game • A game that admits a weighted PF is called a weighted potential game • A game that admits an exact PF is called a potential game • In such games a Nash equilibrium is a local maximum for the potential

  15. Equilibria in Potential Games Thm (MS96) Let G be an ordinal potential game (P is an OPF). A strategy profile s in S is a pure equilibrium point for G iff for every player i it holds P(s) ≥ P(s-i, x) for every x in Si Therefore, if P has maximal value in S, then G has a pure Nash equilibrium. Corollary Every finite OP game has a pure Nash equilibrium.

  16. An example Nash equilibrium P4 maximal value C D C P4 = PD = D Thm (MS96) C D C PD(P4) = D

  17. FIP: an important property • A path in S is a sequence of states s.t. between every consecutive pair of states there is only one deviator • A path is an improvement path w.r.t. G if each deviator has a strict advantage ui(sk) > ui(sk-1) • G has the FIP if every improvement path is finite • Clearly if G has the FIP then G has at least one pure equilibrium • Every improvement path terminates in an equilibrium point

  18. FIP: an important property (2) Lemma Every finite OP game has the FIP. The converse is true? “No” • G’’ has the FIP ((B,A) is an equilibrium) • any OPF must satisfies the following impossible relations: • P(A,A) < P(B,A) < P(B,B) < P(A,B) = P(A,A) A B A G’’ = B Lemma Let G be a finite game. Then, G has the FIP iff G has a generalized ordinal potential function.

  19. FIP: an important property (3) Lemma Let G be a finite game. Then, G has the FIP iff G has a generalized ordinal potential function. Proof: Consider the graph of strict improvement moves. Give v the potential function value = the length of the longest path to a sink

  20. Congestion vs (Exact) Potential Games Thm Every congestion game is an (exact) potential game. Thm Every finite (exact) potential game is isomorphic to a congestion game.

  21. Congestion vs (Exact) Potential Games Thm Every finite (exact) potential game is isomorphic to a congestion game. • Potential game: • n players, k pure strategies each, potential P • Congestion game: • n players, k pure strategies each, 2kn resources • resource associated with {0,1}kn vector

  22. Congestion vs (Exact) Potential Games Thm Every finite (exact) potential game is isomorphic to a congestion game. • Congestion game: • player 1 ≤ i ≤n plays pure strategy 0 ≤ q ≤ k-1: • uses all resources rb where bit bik+q = 1 (2kn-1 res.) • For every strategy vector s (for both games) • b(s)where b(s)ik+q = 1 iff player i uses q in s • For n agents, the cost of rb(s) is P(s), for less agents the cost is 0 • For agent i, let b’ be such that b’jk+q= 0 if user j≠i uses strategy q, 1 otherwise. • Cost of resource rb’ with one user ui(s)-P(s)

  23. Final project part 1 Improve the construction (use less resources) Why?

  24. Computing NE in congestion games • Sometimes easy (polytime) – symmetric network congestion games • Sometimes hard (PLS complete) – general congestion games, symmetric congestion games, general network congestion games

  25. Symmetric network congestion games (easy) • Graph G=(V,E), source vertex v, sink t • n players need to find a path from v to t. • Congestion on edge e is given by c(e,k) where k is the number of players using the edge (c ≥ 0) • Cost to player is sum of costs of edges player uses.

  26. Symmetric network congestion games (easy) (s –strategy, v – source, confusing) • Convert to min-cost flow • Replace edge e in G with n parallel links, of capacity 1, and with costs c(e,1), c(e,2), … c(e,n) • The cost of a min cost flow of value n, (strategy s), from v to t is equal to the potential function

  27. Hardness results: Total Search Problems – TFNP • A search problem S is a set of inputs IS* • Such that: • For every x  IS there is an associated set of solutions • Recognizing if y is a solution can be done in polytime • A search problem is total if Sx is not empty, for all x • r-Nash (r player Nash, normal form) is total, needs accuracy parameter as input (true Nash can be irrational)

  28. Total Search Problems – TFNP • A search problem S is a set of inputs IS* • Such that: • For every x  IS there is an associated set of solutions • Recognizing if y is a solution can be done in polytime • A search problem is total if Sx is not empty, for all x • r-Nash (r player Nash, normal form) is total, needs accuracy parameter as input (true Nash can be irrational)

  29. Subclasses of TFNP – PPAD and PLS • PPAD: Polynomial Parity Argument, Directed Version (or just that Papadimitriou has two p’s). • End of Line problem: • n input bit circuits P and S (predecessor and successor) • S(00…0) ≠ 00….0, P(00…0)=00…0 • Find the end of the line (S(x)=x) or a loop (P(S(x))=x. • PPAD – class of total search problems reducible to “end of line”. • In particular – includes Brower Fixed point (discrete version) • PPAD complete – natural notion. • Brower is complete, 2 Player Nash is also complete. • We saw how to use Brower to solve Nash, other direction also works (major recent result – we will return to it when I understand it).

  30. Subclasses of TFNP – PPAD and PLS • PLS: Polynomial Local Search • A local search problem P belongs to PLS if: • For every instance I, a polytime algorithm A computes an initial feasible solution • A polytime algorithm B that computes, for every instance I and every feasible solution S, the objective function value c(S) • A polytime algorithm C that determines if S is locally optimal for instance I, and if not gives a better solution in the neighborhood of I

  31. PLS reductions • PLS: Polynomial Local Search • A PLS reduction from Problem P to Problem Q: • A polytime function f that takes instances of P {IP} to instances of Q {IQ} • A polytime function g that maps pairs (SQ,IP) to solutions SP of IP. (SQ is a solution of f(IP)). • For all instances IP of P, if SQ is a local optimum of f(IP) then g(SQ,IP) is a local optimum of IP. • P is PLS-Complete – all problems in PLS are PLS reducible to P

  32. PLS Complete problem – max cut (political party game) • Undirected graph G, weights on edges • Find a partition of the vertices so that the sum of the weights of edges crossing the cut is maximized (minimize disagreements within the party, high weight – high disagreement)

  33. NE in a congestion game is PLS complete (even a symmetric congestion game) • For every edge e of weight w: two resources: reR and reL • Every player u has two pure strategies: • Use all resources (reL) for e = (u,v) • Use all resources (reR) for e = (u,v) • If re{L,R} is used by one player only, the cost is zero, if used by two, the cost is the weight of e

More Related