1 / 10

Australia’s regulatory state Definition – measurement – impact – reform

Australia’s regulatory state Definition – measurement – impact – reform. Dr Julie Novak Senior Fellow Institute of Public Affairs. Defining the regulatory state. Governments intervene in economic and social affairs by using an array of instruments and techniques simultaneously. Regulation.

aldis
Download Presentation

Australia’s regulatory state Definition – measurement – impact – reform

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Australia’s regulatory stateDefinition – measurement – impact – reform Dr Julie Novak Senior Fellow Institute of Public Affairs

  2. Defining the regulatory state • Governments intervene in economic and social affairs by using an array of instruments and techniques simultaneously. • Regulation. • Taxation. • Expenditure. • Moral suasion. • What is regulation? • ‘Regulation can be defined as a principle, rule or law designed to control or govern conduct’ (Productivity Commission, 2007). • Distinguish between economic regulation and social regulation. • Distinguish between ‘black letter’ regulation (primary & subordinate legislation) and quasi-regulation (codes of practice, guidance notes, etc.). • Distinguish between government regulation and self-regulation.

  3. Defining the regulatory state • Most economists focus upon fiscal or labour-use measurements of relative public sector size. • Major advantage of these approaches is that the relevant data is more readily available. • But role of government as taxer and spender, and as absorber of real resources, depends upon regulatory authorisation for it to perform those activities. • ‘Government expenditure and employment derive from, but do not themselves constitute, the power of government. Before the government can spend or employ, it must obtain the authority to promote a specified public purpose. If the requisite authority cannot be acquired (a legislative question) and sustained (a judicial question), then the matter is settled: no authority, no program.’ (Robert Higgs, 1987). • Regulation also imperfect substitute for taxation, or even direct government spending and employment.

  4. Measuring the regulatory state • Most popular proxy measure of regulatory burden is number of pages of primary (subordinate) legislation. • New environmental and social legislation, as well as revisions to economic legislation, responsible for upscale of regulatory burden since late 1960s.

  5. Assessing the regulatory state • It is often asserted that regulations are necessary to deliver broad social benefits to the community. • Environmental regulations ensure fresh air, clean water, non-human species protection, and redressing ‘dangerous climate change.’ • Labour market regulations prevent economic exploitation of employees by employers. • Consumer regulations required to ensure customers enjoy safe products that reflect reasonable value. • Usually in ex-post fashion, economists suggest regulations address innumerable forms of ‘market failure’ which, if unaddressed, would emaciate private sector activities. • Public choice theorists ask question as to ‘who benefits’ from regulatory state (it is general public at large; or is it crony capitalists, other special interests, or even political class itself?).

  6. Assessing the regulatory state • Many proponents of government regulation – politicians, bureaucrats, direct beneficiaries – argue there is some benefit attributable to regulatory activity. • But there are also always costs of regulation. • Most commonly known, and more easily identifiable, costs are the compliance costs of regulation. • Administrative compliance costs. • Costs of filling out and submitting paperwork; record keeping costs; costs of obtaining external advice. • Other compliance costs. • Costs for additional staff hiring and training; capital holding costs associated with regulatory delays; time spent in meeting regulatory requirements. • Dynamic effects of regulation. • Regulations redirect entrepreneurial initiative towards less value-adding pursuits; capacity to eek out regulatory holidays through political lobbying encourages ‘rent seeking.’

  7. Assessing the regulatory state • Estimating the burdens posed by Australian regulation: • Early estimates of total regulatory burden, by Dr Alan Moran, between $40bn and $80bn in mid-1980s (incl. paperwork, other compliance costs). • OECD (2001): compliance burdens of tax, employment & environment regulations equivalent to 3.4% of GDP. • Productivity Commission (2007): reducing compliance costs of regulation by 20% would lead to ‘resource savings’ of $8bn. • ANU (2009): direct costs of EPBC Act impact assessments and approvals totalling $820m (over life of Act). • ACCI (2012): 12% of red tape survey respondents spent more than 20 hours pw on compliance; almost 50% spent more than $10,000 on compliance activities.

  8. Reforming the regulatory state • Regulatory ‘repeal day’ at federal level a welcome first step (but many more repeal days needed!). • Quality of regulation, and reform governance processes, also important to help slow down rate of regulatory growth. • Need more credible ‘regulatory impact statements’ that incorporate a genuine cost-benefit analysis of regulatory impacts (instead of sweeping assertion of benefits, and crudely devised cost analyses). • All legislation, existing and new, should be accompanied by a ‘sunset clause’ encouraging reassessment of need for the regulations. • ‘One-in, one-out’ rules to stabilise flow of legislation through parliament, or ‘one-in, x-out’ (x>1) to reduce flows.

  9. Reforming the regulatory state • Immense barriers to meaningful reduction of regulatory burdens in modern political culture. • Special interests, and voters benefiting from regulations, will spend time and resources defending their preferred regulatory settings. • But the benefits of shifting the political culture towards a climate favourable to deregulation could be immense. • Effect of Adam Smith’s epochal critique of mercantilism on the British regulatory environment: • ‘from the Statute of Merton (20 Henry III.), to the end of 1872, there had been passed 18,110 public acts, of which it is estimated that four-fifths had been wholly or partially repealed’ (Bruce Smith, 1887). • Where is our modern-day Adam Smith, who can reveal the follies of hyper-regulation, in a persuasive way, to the layperson, setting the scene for the next wave of liberal reform?

  10. The regulatory state: What you can do about it • Use your growing influence within the Liberal Party to praise Abbott and state governments for good deregulatory deeds, and encourage them to move further, in the face of crony & special interest resistance. • Build political-name recognition in your own communities by championing a deregulatory cause, either at the local, state, or federal level. • Don’t be afraid to publicly critique outrageous regulatory proposals by Labor-Green alliance – signal to others that someone, somewhere does care about our liberties and way of life. • Free-market think tanks are here to communicate liberty’s principles and contemporary policy issues to the general public. • Inform usabout your experiences of onerous regulation and nuisance red tape, so we can communicate the problems to the public, and influence the politicians to do right thing. • Also, please join us or donate to us, so we can continue our good works in the name of freedom!

More Related