1 / 28

Experiments

Experiments. on combinatorial auctions. Only some of the techniques of CABOB deployed in these results. Experimental setup. Comparison between CABOB and CPLEX 7.0 CPLEX 7.0 was the fastest earlier algorithm for the problem System: 933 MHz Pentium III, 512 MB RAM, Linux 2.2

Albert_Lan
Download Presentation

Experiments

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Experiments on combinatorial auctions Only some of the techniques of CABOB deployed in these results

  2. Experimental setup • Comparison between CABOB and CPLEX 7.0 • CPLEX 7.0 was the fastest earlier algorithm for the problem • System: 933 MHz Pentium III, 512 MB RAM, Linux 2.2 • 100 instances for each data point • All distributions produced distinct bids

  3. Experiments: Random Distribution • Random: Choose a random number of items without • replacement. Pick price from [0,1]. [Sandholm IJCAI-99] • CABOB does well primarily because of column dominance test. • CPLEX is able to solve these without searching 47% of the time.

  4. Experiments: Weighted Random Distribution • Weighted Random: Choose a random number of items without • replacement. Pick the price from between 0 and the number of • items in the bid. [Sandholm IJCAI-99] • CPLEX only searches 5% of the time. • CABOB searches 88% of the time.

  5. Experiments: CATS Distributions • CATS: Combinatorial Auction Test Suite [Leyton-Brown,Pearson, Shoham, 2000] • Random bid distributions • Modeled after realistic bidder preferences • Distributions have many parameters; we varied # bids and used default parameters for rest

  6. Experiments: CATS PATHS • CATS PATHS • Simulates bids on paths in a 2-D space. • Examples: truck routes, bandwidth allocation • Neither algorithm searched. CABOB’s simple preprocessing • techniques are faster

  7. Experiments: CATS MATCHING • CATS MATCHING • Simulates bid where complementarity is based on a temporal aspect of items • Example: airport take-off and landing slots • CPLEX never searched, CABOB rarely searched

  8. Experiment: Uniform Distribution • Each bid has same number of items • Prices chosen at random from [0,1] • Cases with few items per bid were hardest for earlier algorithms [Sandholm IJCAI-99, Fujishima et al IJCAI-99]

  9. Experiments: Bounded Distribution… • Bounded: Choose number of items between a lower and upper bound. Pick price between 0 and number of items in bid • Similar to Uniform distribution [Sandholm IJCAI-99], but more realistic • CABOB performs better here mainly because of the complete bid graph test

  10. Experiments: Components Distribution • A number of independent components from the uniform distribution where each bid has same #items • CABOB’s decomposition techniques capitalize on this structure, CPLEX does not

  11. Anytime Performance • Feasible solution found quickly • Solution improves rapidly over time • Optimal algorithms might be the best approximation algorithms too !

  12. Generalizations of combinatorial auctions • Free disposal • Substitutability • Multiple units of each item • Combinatorial exchanges (= many-to-many auctions) • Reservation prices • On items • On combinations • With substitutability • Combinatorial reverse auctions • Combinations of these generalizations

  13. Generalization: substitutability [Sandholm IJCAI-99] • What if agent 1 bids • $7 for {1,2} • $4 for {1} • $5 for {2} ? • Bids joined with XOR • Allows bidders to express general preferences • Groves-Clarke pricing mechanism can be applied to make truthful bidding a dominant strategy • Worst case: Need to bid on all 2#items-1 combinations • OR-of-XORs bids maintain full expressiveness & are more concise • E.g. (B2XOR B3) OR (B1XOR B3XOR B4) OR ... • Our algorithm applies (simply more edges in bid graph )

  14. Winner determination in combinatorial auction generalizations Tuomas Sandholm Subhash Suri Andrew Gilpin David Levine Carnegie Mellon University University of California CombineNet Inc. Computer Science Department Santa Barbara Pittsburgh, PA Dept of Computer Science

  15. New generalizations of combinatorial auctions • No free disposal (sellers cannot keep items, buyers cannot take extras) • Single- or multi-unit • Combinatorial reverse auctions • Single- or multi-unit • Combinatorial exchanges (= many-to-many auctions) • Single- or multi-unit

  16. Combinatorial reverse auction • Example: procurement in supply chains • Auctioneer wants to buy a set of items (has to get all) • Can take extras if there is free disposal • Sellers place bids on how cheaply they are willing to sell bundles of items • Thrm. Winner determination is NP-complete even in single-unit case with free disposal • Thrm. Single unit case with free disposal is approximable • k = 1 + log m (m = largest number of items that any bid contains) • Greedy algorithm: Keep choosing bid with lowest price / #items

  17. No free disposal • Free disposal: seller can keep items, buyers can take extras • Free disposal has been assumed in the combinatorial auction literature so far • In practice, freeness of disposal can vary across items & bidders • Without free disposal, the set of feasible solutions is same for combinatorial auctions & reverse auctions • Thrm. Even finding a feasible solution is NP-complete

  18. Combinatorial exchange • Example bid: (buy 20 tons of water, sell 10 cubic meters of hydrogen, sell 5 cubic meters of oxygen, ask $500) • Example application: manufacturing where a participant bids for inputs & outputs of a production plan simultaneously • Label bids as winning or losing so as to maximize (revealed) surplus: sum of amounts paid by bidders minus sum of amounts paid to bidders • On each item, sell quantity  buy quantity • Equality if there is no free disposal • Thrm. NP-complete even in the single-unit case • Thrm. Inapproximable even in the single-unit case • Could also maximize trading volume • Thrm. Without free disposal, even finding a feasible solution is NP-complete (even in the single-unit case)

  19. Experiments on generalizations • 933 MHz Pentium III, 512M RAM • CPLEX 7.0 • Each plot point is mean over 50 instances • Significantly slower to find optimal solution than to prove infeasibility => we plot times on feasible instances • With free disposal, all instances are feasible • On distributions where CPLEX finds optimum with no search, it also tends to prove infeasibility with no search • On distributions where CPLEX needs search to find optimum, it also tends to need search to prove infeasibility

  20. Lack of free disposal makes problem much harder Complexity is polynomial in bids (even in worst case) Reverse auctions with free disposal seldom require search on these distributions Auctions require more search & more often (as inapproximability suggests) Single unit auctions & reverse auctions

  21. Single unit auctions & reverse auctions… • On decay distribution, even with free disposal, reverse auctions take longer than auctions (unlike approximability would suggest)

  22. Multi-unit auctions & reverse auctions • Decay-decay: Number of units for each item chosen with decay probability .99 • For each bid • Number of items chosen with decay probability a1 • For each item, #units chosen with decay probability a2 • All instances were easy. E.g., at a1 = .6, a2 = .9, LP solved • 74% of reverse auctions with free disposal • 52% of auctions with free disposal • 50% of auctions without free disposal • 22% of reverse auctions without free disposal • Hardest setting (a1 = .8, a2 = .8):

  23. Multi-unit auctions & reverse auctions… • CATS multipaths: • Almost all reverse auctions (with/without free disposal) & auctions without free disposal were infeasible • CPLEX could not scale to 2,000 bids on auctions with free disposal

  24. Exchanges • Exchange decay-decay distribution: For each bid • Number of items chosen with decay probability a1 • For each item, #units chosen with decay probability a2 • Sign is negated w.p. .5 • Price is random number between 0 and 1, multiplied by total #units (negative half the time) • Single unit case comes from a2 = 0 • Single-unit of each item • Scales well • Free disposal case slightly harder

  25. Multi-unit exchanges • CPLEX 7.1 scales very poorly: #bids/#items = 10 (a1 = .8, a2 = .8)

  26. Multi-unit exchanges • 50 items, 500 bids (a1 = .8, a2 = .8) • CPLEX 7.1 never finished • Without free disposal, did not even find a feasible solution • CPLEX 7.1 had very poor anytime performance:

  27. Conclusions • Generalizations of combinatorial auctions • No free disposal • Reverse auctions • Exchanges • Single- and multi-unit settings • Theoretical results • All these generalizations are NP-complete • With free disposal • Auction and exchanges are inapproximable • Reverse auctions are approximable • Even finding a feasible solution is NP-complete if XORs are allowed • Without free disposal, even finding a feasible solution is NP-complete • Experimental results • Search does well on auctions & at times even better on reverse auctions • Search does well on single-unit exchanges, poorly on multi-unit exchanges • Better algorithms needed • Lack of free disposal makes the problem much harder

  28. Hot off the press[Kothari, Suri & Sandholm 2002] • Q: How many bids have to be accepted fractionally (in worst case) so as to obtain maximum surplus in a multi-item multi-unit combinatorial exchange / combinatorial auction? • Trivial answer: #bids • A: #items (this is independent of #units) • Q: How many bids have to be accepted fractionally (in worst case) so as to maximize liquidity in a multi-item multi-unit combinatorial exchange? • Trivial answer: #bids • A: #items + 1 (this is independent of #units) • Q: How complex is it to find such a solution? • A: Polynomial time = fast

More Related