1 / 53

Readings

Readings. Readings. Baye 6 th edition or 7 th edition, Chapter 11. Overview. Overview. Overview. Markup Rules. Markup Rules. Markup Rules. Overview

yachi
Download Presentation

Readings

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Readings • Readings • Baye 6th edition or 7th edition, Chapter 11 BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  2. Overview • Overview BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  3. Overview BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  4. Markup Rules • Markup Rules BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  5. Markup Rules Overview Markup Rules for a monopolized good determine price equal marginal cost times a decreasing function of own price elasticity of demand. — So, Apple has high markup since Apple demand has low elasticity. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  6. Markup Rules A Linear Example of Uniform Pricing • As a benchmark for this lesson, consider a firm with linear demand and cost • P = 10 - 2Q • C(Q) = 2Q • If the firm must charge the same price per unit to all consumers, find the profit-maximizing quantity by setting MR(Q) = MC(Q) • 10 - 4Q = 2, so Q* = 2 • Then, find price from demand, P* = 10 - 2(2) = 6 • Profits = (6)(2) - 2(2) = $8. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  7. Markup Rules Graphing Uniform Pricing Price Profits from uniform pricing = $8 10 8 6 4 MC 2 P = 10 - 2Q 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity MR = 10 - 4Q BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  8. Markup Rules Potential Non-Standard Profits Price Consumer surplus that might be captured = $4 10 Profits from uniform pricing = $8 8 6 Deadweight loss that might be captured = $4 4 MC 2 P = 10 - 2Q 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity MR = 10 - 4Q BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  9. Markup Rules The Standard Markup Rule for Non-Linear Demand • Let E denote the own price elasticity of demand for a firm’s product. • Since MR = P[1 + E]/ E, setting MR = MC and simplifying yields the standard markup rule: P = [E/(1+ E)]  MC. • The optimal price is a proportional markup over marginal cost. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  10. Markup Rules An Example • Elasticity of demand for Kodak film is -2. • P = [E/(1+ E)]  MC • P = [-2/(1 - 2)]  MC • P = 2  MC • Price is twice marginal cost. • Fifty percent of Kodak’s price is margin above manufacturing costs (marginal cost). BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  11. Markup Rules Markup Rule and Market Power • Market Power for any firm is inversely related to the magnitude of own-price elasticity. So, according to the markup rule, higher market power means higher price. • For Apple computers elasticity is lower, say E= -2, so P = [E/(1+E)]MC = 2MC • For HP computers elasticity is higher, say E= -4, so P = [E/(1+E)]MC = (4/3)MC • For a perfectly competition, the own-price elasticity E= -∞, so the rule P = [E/(1+ E)]  MC = [1-(1/(1+ E))]  MC is P = [1-(1/(1-∞))]  MC = 1  MC or P = MC. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  12. Perfect Price Discrimination • Perfect Price Discrimination BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  13. Perfect Price Discrimination Overview Perfect Price Discrimination yields maximum possible profit (capturing all consumer surplus and recovering and capturing all deadweight loss) by charging higher prices equal to willingness to pay for initial units rather than a uniform price equal to willingness to pay for the marginal unit. Perfect price discrimination requires perfect knowledge of willingness to pay for each unit and for each consumer. --- Peter may be charged $4 for his first unit and $2 for his second unit, and Paul may be charged $6 for his first unit and $1 for his second unit. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  14. Perfect Price Discrimination Example from CNN.com: • According to a recent study, many consumers are unaware that price discrimination occurs over the Internet. • The Internet allows shoppers to easily compare prices across thousands of stores. But it also enables businesses to collect detailed information about a customer's purchasing history, preferences, and financial resources -- and to set prices accordingly. • So when you buy an airplane ticket or a DVD online, you may pay a higher -- or lower -- price than another customer buying the very same item from the very same site. • Why? Because the information the site has compiled on you suggests that you may be willing to pay more -- or less -- than others for that item. • (Another reason for price discrimination is to measure demand. The company my be conducting random price tests to figure out what is the ideal price point for its product.) BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  15. Perfect Price Discrimination • Until now, all models involved a single optimum price. • But there is more profit in charging different prices. • Price discrimination is the practice of charging different prices to consumers for the same good. • Price discrimination can be perfect or imperfect. • Perfect price discrimination achieves maximum profits, leaving no surplus for consumers. • Imperfect price discrimination achieves less than maximum profits, and leaves some surplus for consumers. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  16. Perfect Price Discrimination Perfect Price Discrimination • Practice of charging each consumer the maximum amount he or she will pay for each incremental unit (the height of the demand curve). • Permits a firm to extract all surplus from consumers and to recover all deadweight loss. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  17. Perfect Price Discrimination Perfect Price Discrimination Price Profits*: .5(4-0)(10 - 2) = $16 10 8 6 Total Cost* =$8 4 2 MC D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity * Assuming no fixed costs BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  18. Perfect Price Discrimination Example: • A Pepperdine professor visiting Mexico paid $15 for a chess set (about equal to the maximum he was willing to pay). • When he returned to the same store, he was offered a lower price on a second set. After refusing the offer, the price continued to lower as the manager read his posture and tried to figure out the maximum amount he would be willing to pay. • Some say perfect price discrimination won’t work if consumers can resell the good. It does get harder, but it is still possible: • Suppose a Pepperdine student is only willing to pay $10 for a chess set for himself, but that student could resell the set to the professor for $15. • How much would the student be charged for the first set? • For the second set? (the one he keeps for himself) BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  19. Perfect Price Discrimination Caveat: • Information constraints make perfect price discrimination difficult (it is difficult to know how much someone is willing to pay). • The information constraints are especially difficult if consumers can resell the good. • The manager cannot just appraise the maximum price the customer before him would pay for the good if he were buying it for himself, but also how much that customer could get by reselling the good. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  20. Block Pricing • Block Pricing BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  21. Block Pricing Overview Block Pricing packages goods into a block. Block pricing yields maximum possible profit from each consumer (just like Perfect Price Discrimination) when the block price results in an average price per unit equal to the average willingness to pay. Knowing the profit-maximizing block price for each consumer requires perfect knowledge of willingness to pay for each unit. --- Peter may be charged $6 for a bag of 6 cookies, and Paul may be charged $3 for a bag of 4 cookies. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  22. Block Pricing Block Pricing • When consumers can not resell the good and when the firm has unlimited information, block pricing generates the same maximum profit as perfect price discrimination. • The practice of packaging multiple units of an identical product together and selling them as one package. • Examples • Paper. • Six-packs of soda. • Different sized of cans of green beans. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  23. Block Pricing An Algebraic Example • Typical consumer’s demand is P = 10 - 2Q • C(Q) = 2Q • Optimal number of units in a package? • Optimal package price? BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  24. Block Pricing Optimal Quantity To Package: 4 Units Price 10 8 6 4 MC = AC 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  25. Block Pricing Optimal Price for the Package: $24 Price Consumer’s valuation of 4 units = .5(8)(4) + (2)(4) = $24 Therefore, set P = $24. 10 8 6 4 MC = AC 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  26. Block Pricing Costs and Profits with Block Pricing Price 10 Profits* = [.5(8)(4) + (2)(4)] – (2)(4) = $16 8 6 4 Costs = (2)(4) = $8 2 MC = AC D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity * Assuming no fixed costs BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  27. Commodity Bundling • Commodity Bundling BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  28. Commodity Bundling Overview Commodity Bundling packages non-identical goods into a block or bundle. Commodity bundling can yield more profit than uniform pricing (but not maximum possible profit) by charging an average price per unit equal to the average willingness to pay. Commodity bundling may yield more profit than block pricing when the seller does not know the profit-maximizing block price for each consumer. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  29. Commodity Bundling Commodity Bundling • The practice of bundling two or more differentiated products together and charging one price for the bundle. • Examples • Vacation packages. • Computers and software. • Film and developing. • Commodity bundling is always possible because there are no information constraints (unlike first-order price discrimination). • Commodity bundling is sometimes profitable, sometimes not. • Let’s see an example of each. • Examples hint at a rule for when bundling is profitable. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  30. Commodity Bundling Example of unprofitable bundling • Two products (combs and head wax), zero production cost. • Two consumers (Fabio and Bruce Willis) • Fabio would pay $1 for a comb and $0 for head wax. • Bruce would pay $0 for a comb and $3 for head wax. • If the goods are sold separately, compute the optimum non-discriminating prices? • $1 per comb, $3 for head wax. Profit = $4. • If the goods are bundled, compute the optimum price for the bundle of 1 comb and 1 jar of head wax? • Fabio would pay $1 for the bundle (tossing the wax). • Bruce would pay $3 for the bundle (tossing the comb). • Optimum price is $3. Profit = $3. • It was better to keep the products unbundled. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  31. Commodity Bundling Example of profitable bundling: The Kodak Moment • Total market size for film and developing is 4 million consumers. • Four types of consumers • 25% will use only Kodak film (F). • 25% will use only Kodak developing (D). • 25% will use only Kodak film and use only Kodak developing (FD). • 25% have no preference (N). • Zero costs (for simplicity). • Maximum price each type of consumer will pay is as follows: BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  32. Commodity Bundling Reservation Prices (maximum consumers are willing to pay) for Kodak Film and Developing by Type of Consumer: BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  33. Commodity Bundling • Optimal Film Price? • Assume no production cost. • Optimal Price is $8; only types F and FD buy, resulting in profit of $8 x 2 million = $16 Million. • At a price of $4, only types F, FD, and D will buy, profits = $12 Million. • At a price of $3, all will types will buy, profit = $12 Million. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  34. Commodity Bundling • Optimal Developing Price? • Assume no production cost. • At a price of $6, only “D” type buys, profit = $6 Million. • At a price of $4, “D” and “FD” buy, profit = $8 Million. • Optimal price $3, only types “F”, “FD”, and “D” buy, profits = $9 Million. • At a price of $2, all will types will buy, profit = $8 Million. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  35. Commodity Bundling • Total Profits by Pricing Each Item Separately. • Assume no production cost. • Total Profit = Film Profits + Development Profits • Total Profit = $16 Million + $9 Million = $25 Million. • The firm can earn even greater profits by bundling. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  36. Commodity Bundling • Consumer valuation of a “Bundle” of Film and Developing • Assume no production cost. • Do not allow consumers to separately buy Film and Developing. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  37. Commodity Bundling • Optimal Bundle Price? • Assume no production cost. • At a price of $12, only “FD” type buys, profit = $12 Million. • At a price of $11, “F” and “FD” buy, profit = $22 Million. • Optimal price $10, only types “F”, “FD”, and “D” buy, profits = $30 Million. • At a price of $5, all will types will buy, profit = $20 Million. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  38. Two-Part Pricing • Two-Part Pricing BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  39. Two-Part Pricing Overview Two Part Pricing charges both a customer fee and a uniform price per unit. Two-part pricing yields maximum possible profit from each consumer (just like Perfect Price Discrimination) when the uniform price equals marginal cost and the customer fee equals consumer surplus, and when customers cannot buy then resell to other customers. Knowing the profit-maximizing two-part price for each consumer requires perfect knowledge of consumer surplus. --- Peter may be charged $36 for admission to Disneyland and a price of $0 (= marginal cost) per ride, and Paul may be charged $13 and a price of $0 per ride. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  40. Two-Part Pricing Two-Part Pricing • When consumers can not resell the good and when the firm has unlimited information, two-part pricing generates the same maximum profit as perfect price discrimination. • Two-part pricing consists of a fee and a per unit charge. • Examples: • Disneyland with admission fee and zero per ride. • $2 cokes with free-refills ($2 fee and zero per refill). • Athletic club memberships. • Netflix with monthly fee and free movie streaming. • Spotify with monthly fee and free music streaming. • Other examples? BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  41. Two-Part Pricing How Two-Part Pricing Works Price 1. Set price at marginal cost (to maximize total surplus). 2. Compute consumer surplus. 3. Charge a fixed-fee equal to consumer surplus (to capture all surplus as profit). 10 8 6 Fixed Fee = Profits* = $16 Per Unit Charge 4 MC 2 D * Assuming no fixed costs 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity

  42. Group Pricing • Group Pricing BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  43. Group Pricing Overview Group Pricing applies markup rules for groups like seniors, students, and kids. Group pricing yields more profit than uniform pricing but less than maximum profits. Group pricing does not require perfect knowledge of each consumer. — So, Knott’s Berry Farm discounts to seniors because seniors cannot survive Knott’s distinctive thrill rides. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  44. Group Pricing Imperfect Price Discrimination • Third-degree price discrimination: The practice of charging different groups of consumers different prices for the same product. • Group must have observable characteristics for third-degree price discrimination to work. • Examples: • Student discounts • Child discounts • Poverty discounts (like when poor people clip coupons) • Senior citizen’s discounts • Regional and international pricing. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  45. Group Pricing Implementing Third-Degree Price Discrimination • Suppose the total demand for a product is comprised of two groups with different elasticities, E1 < E2 < - 1 • Notice that group 1 is more price sensitive than group 2. • Profit-maximizing prices? • P1 = [E1/(1+ E1)]  MC < [E2/(1+ E2)]  MC = P2 Qualitative Examples • Why are seniors charged less than others at Disneyland and at restaurants? Higher elasticity (more substitutes). • They shop at Disneyland, like they shop at the mall. • They eat plain food at restaurants, like they eat at home. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  46. Group Pricing A Numerical Example • Suppose the elasticity of demand for Kodak film in the US is EU = -1.5, and the elasticity of demand in Japan is EJ = -2.5. • Marginal cost of manufacturing film is $3. • PU = [EU/(1+ EU)]  MC = [-1.5/(1 - 1.5)]  $3 = $9 • PJ = [EJ/(1+ EJ)]  MC = [-2.5/(1 - 2.5)]  $3 = $5 • Kodak’s optimal third-degree pricing strategy is to charge a higher price in the US, where demand is less elastic. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  47. Summary • Summary BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  48. Summary Summary • Consider a monopolist with demand Q = 100 – 0.1P and constant unit cost of 500. • The Lesson covered three levels (orders) of price discrimination: • Perfect discrimination, including two-part pricing and block pricing. • Commodity bundling and imperfect discrimination. • No price discrimination. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  49. Summary • No price discrimination • Q = 100 – 0.1P implies P = 1,000 – 10Q • MR = 1,000 – 20Q • MC = 500 • MR = MC implies 1,000 – 20Q = 500, or Q = 25. • P = 1,000 – 10(25) = 750 • P = (P-MC)Q - FC = (750-500)(25) – 10,000 = -3,750 BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

  50. Summary • Perfect price discrimination: Two-part price. • P(Q) = 1,000 – 10Q • P(Q) = MC implies 1,000 – 10Q = 500, and Q = 50. • Firm breaks even on P = MC per unit profit. • Consumer surplus triangle = .5(1,000-500)(25) = 12,500. • Fee = Consumer surplus = 12,500. • Profit = 12,500 – 10,000 = 2,500. BA 445 Lesson A.10 Monopoly Pricing

More Related