1 / 44

ECON7003, 2008-9. Money and Banking. Hugh Goodacre. Lectures 1-2. LIQUIDITY DEMAND AND B ANK RUNS

ECON7003, 2008-9. Money and Banking. Hugh Goodacre. Lectures 1-2. LIQUIDITY DEMAND AND B ANK RUNS. Bank deposits and uncertain liquidity demand . Trading risk in a two-individual ‘society’. Intermediation: the bank deposit contract. Ranking outcomes. ‘Autarchy’. Intermediation with no run.

suzy
Download Presentation

ECON7003, 2008-9. Money and Banking. Hugh Goodacre. Lectures 1-2. LIQUIDITY DEMAND AND B ANK RUNS

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. ECON7003, 2008-9. Money and Banking. Hugh Goodacre.Lectures 1-2.LIQUIDITY DEMAND AND BANK RUNS Bank deposits and uncertain liquidity demand. • Trading risk in a two-individual ‘society’. • Intermediation: the bank deposit contract. Ranking outcomes. • ‘Autarchy’. • Intermediation with no run. • Intermediation with run and without deposit insurance. • Intermediation with run with deposit insurance. Measures to prevent bank runs. • Suspension of convertibility. • Government-backed deposit insurance. • Lender of last resort facility.

  2. Withdrawal of deposits on demand normally no problem, despite: • low deposit : asset ratio • high gearing in bank sector • (a) Scale economies: • → withdrawal demands unlikely to be correlated. • For banking system as a whole, likely to be inversely correlated: • Debits-credits net out! • (b) Tradable money market instruments: • e.g. Certificates of Deposit (CDs). • To meet fluctuations in liquidity needs.

  3. These advantages are basic to bank’s profit through intermediation: • i.e.Asset transformation: • Short-term / instantly withdrawable deposits → long-term / illiquid assets • ‘Maturity transformation’ • Small-size deposits → large-size assets: • ‘Size transformation’ • Low-risk instrument, i.e. deposit, → high-risk.: • ‘Risk transformation’ • In each case: • Interest on asset > interest on liability → bank profit.

  4. BUT: • Loss of confidence in bank • → withdrawals not motivated by ‘genuine’ liquidity requirement / transactions motive. • May be contagious and → panic. • In panic,those at end of queue may not be paid in full: • Even if bank is solvent and all its assets are liquidated

  5. Costs of liquidation • Loss of: • customer relationships • confidential information, etc. • i.e. Destruction of ‘informational capital’ / intangible assets. • Inevitably undervalued in ‘fire sale’ conditions. • → Net value > 0 when functioning • may → < 0 if sold off hurriedly.

  6. Asymmetric information problem facing bank: • Bank unable to distinguish between: • withdrawals for ‘genuine’ / transactions purposes • withdrawals through panic • → cannot pay ‘in sequence’: • Gain time → avoid fire sale • → liquidate assets at better price.

  7. 3-period model of bank runs and measures to prevent them. • Assumption: • Bank liabilities all consist of deposits withdrawable on demand. • Each individual has a primary investment of 1 in period 0 • yields 1 if liquidated and consumed in period 1 • yields R > 1 if liquidated and consumed in period 2. • i.e. R ≡ 1 + r • i.e. Requirement for liquidation of investment in period 1 drives the demand for liquidity. • ‘Cost of early death’ is R – 1. • Because R > 1, type 2s optimally set C1 = 0.

  8. Individuals are of 2 types: • Type 1s ‘die’ in period 1 • having first liquidated their investment and consumed its entire value. • Type 2s survive period 1 but ‘die’ in period 2 • having by that time liquidated their investment and consumed its entire value. • The overall proportion (p) of type 1s is publicly knownin period 0 • i.e. There is no aggregate uncertainy. • but individuals do not find out which type they are until period 1, and this information is private. • i.e. There is individual uncertainy.

  9. Individual’s expected utility E [U] in period 0: • E [U] = p.U(C11 + C21) + (1 – p).U(C12 + C22) • Type 1s: Expectation of a constant is a constant → • E[C11] = C11 = 1 • E[C21] = C21 = 0 • Type 2s: Expectation that they optimise → • E[C12] = 0 • E[C22] = R • → Substituting: • E [U] = p.U(1 + 0) + (1 – p).U(0 + R) • → E [U] = p.U(1) + (1 – p).U(R)

  10. ‘Society’ of two individuals where p = ½ • Learning own type ≡ revelation of type of other ! • i.e. Full ‘state verification’ / no informational asymmetry. • → Socially optimal risk-sharing contract possible in period 0: • Type 2 will pay fixed sum (π) to type 1 in period 1. • → Individual 1 consumes C1 = 1 + π in period 1. • Individual 2 consumes C2 = R(1 – π) in period 2. • Only requirement: • Mechanism for enforcing contract.

  11. ‘Society’ of two individuals, contd • Deriving optimal scale of transfer (π): • We need to find the value of π which maximises total social utility (SU) ≡ U(C1) + U(C2) • Express period 2 budget constraint i.t.o. C1: • C1 = 1 + π • → π = C1 - 1 • Substituting into C2 = R(1 – π) we have: • C2 = R[1 – (C1 – 1)] • = R(2 – C1) = 2R – RC1 • Substituting into expression for total social utility, we have: • SU = U(C1) + U(2R – RC1)

  12. ‘Society’ of two individuals, contd • Differentiating SU and setting to zero to maximise, we have: • SU = U(C1) + U(2R – RC1) • → dSU / dC1 = MU1 – R.MU2 = 0 • → MU1 / MU2 = R • = 1 + r • i.e. MRS (in consumption) = MRT (through investment) • We define the values which solve these equations as: • C1*, C2*, and π*

  13. C2 ‘Society’ of two individuals, contd 2R • ← Vertical intercept: • Period 2 social budget constraint: • C2 = R(2 – C1) • Solving for C1 = 0: • C2 = 2R Horizontal intercept: Maximum possible consumption by both types (‘social’ consumption) is 2. ↓ Social budget line 2 C1

  14. A C2 ‘Society’ of two individuals, contd 2R Allocation point under autarchy / no trading of risk R • i.e. Social level of consumption under autarchy is: • 1 + R 1 2 C1

  15. C2 ‘Society’ of two individuals, contd 2R 450 line indicates complete absence of risk between ‘states’ / outcomes 450 2 C1

  16. A A' ‘Society’ of two individuals, contd C2 With trading in risk / contract to pay π, ‘social IC’ reaches tangency with BC at A' With no trading in risk, ‘social indifference curve’ cuts BC at A 2R A' is closer to the 450 line, indicating a reduction in risk R It is on a higher social IC curve, showing that trading in risk results in a socially preferable outcome to autarchy. 450 1 2 C1

  17. C2 ‘Society’ of two individuals, contd 2R At A', individual 2 consumes C2* due to loss of Rπ* A R Rπ* A' C2* At A', individual 1 consumes C1* due to receiving π* Note: C2* > C1* π* 450 C1* 1 2 C1

  18. BUT: • Society of more than two individuals: • Information on own type remains private in period 1: • → life expectancy and liquidity requirements no longer publicly revealed. • → asymmetric information problem in designing contract for trading risk.

  19. An intermediary / bank now offers a deposit contract capable of achieving same degree of insurance as in the two-individual case. • i.e. : • All type 1s will consume C1* = 1 + π in period 1. • All type 2s will consume C2* = R(1 – π) in period 2. • C2* > C1* → type 2s still have motive to set C1 = 0

  20. BUT: Bank can only fulfil this contract if only type 1s withdraw their deposits in period 1. • i.e. for ‘genuine’ liquidity requirement. • Fragility of this result: • In period 1 liabilities > assets • → bank relies on type 2s not withdrawing.

  21. Period 1 liabilities > assets: • Recall the assumption: All the bank’s assets / funds are sourced from its depositors. • Let there be N depositors, then the funds available to the bank for distribution to depositors in period 1 are: • N.1 = N • The bank’s liabilities to depositors in period 1 are: • N.C1* • And N.C1* > N !

  22. Let p = ½ • ‘Good’ outcome period 1: • Type 2s will optimise by setting C12 = 0 • Only type 1s withdraw deposits in period 1. • → Liquidity demand in period 1 is: • pNC1* + (1 – p)N.0 • = ½NC1* < N • i.e. Bank’s liabilities do not exceed its assets. • All deposit withdrawal demands can be met.

  23. ‘Bad’ outcome period 1: • Type 2s fear a bank run / begin to withdraw deposits in period 1. • If all do so (‘bank panic’), type 2 liquidity demand in period 1 is: • (1-p).NC1* = ½NC1*. • → Total liquidity demand: • ½NC1* + ½NC1* • = NC1* > N • i.e. Bank’s assets insufficient to meet liabilities. • Some depositors get 0.

  24. Deposit : liability ratio of banks in period 1: • N : N.C1* • i.e. 1 : C1* • Assumption: No deposit insurance arrangements are in place. • Maximum proportion of depositors who can withdraw their deposits in period 1 in the presence of a run: • Deposits divided by liabilities: • N / NC* • i. e. deposits : liabilities ratio (1 : C1*) expressed as a fraction: • f = 1 / C1* • C1* > 1 • → f < 1

  25. Fraction of depositors who get nothing through being last in the queue: • 1 – f • = 1 - 1 / C1* • = (C1* - 1) / C1* • We have: C1* = 1 + π • Substituting: 1 – f = (1 + π – 1) / C1* = π / C1* • i.e. Fraction who receive nothing is π / C1*

  26. i.e. Intermediation / bank deposits offer solution to informational problems of trading in risk of early death. • BUT • That solution is not robust to fear of bank’s insolvency: • Such fear may → self-fulfilling prophecy / fear becomes general (‘panic’). • ‘Sequential service constraint’ / bank cannot meet all withdrawal demands / ‘last in queue’ get nothing. • Expectations of run may → actual run, with no change in fundamentals. • Banks are inherently ‘fragile’. • If fear is contagious, may threaten whole banking system.

  27. Preview: The ‘good’ and ‘bad’ outcomes will be defined as Nash equilibria. • Measures to prevent bank runs. • Influence expectations / provide confidence. • Make ‘good’ Nash equilibrium unique. • 3 possible solutions: • Action by banks themselves: • Suspend convertibility • Government actions: • Government-backed deposit insurance • Lender of last resort facility

  28. ‘AUTARCHY’ / no trading in risk – review: • E [U] = ½ [U(1) + U(R)] • ‘Society’ of two individuals where p = ½ • E [U] = ½[U(C1*) + U(C2*)] • ≡ What is offered by intermediary. • The ‘good’ Nash equilibrium

  29. ‘Society’ of two individuals where p = ½ -- review. • Scale of π* through simple calculus by maximising • SU ≡ U(C1) + U(C2) • Substitute into this the period 2 BC, i.e. 2R – RC1 • Differentiate w.r.t. C1 and set to 0, etc. • i.e. MRS (in consumption) = MRT (through investment) • Values which solve these equations ≡ C1*, C2*, π* • Giving us: • E [U] = ½[U(C1*) + U(C2*)]

  30. Intermediary / bank offers deposit contract providing same degree of insurance as in two-individual case -- review. • C2* > C1* → type 2s still have motive to set C12 = 0 • Fragility of this result: • In period 1 liabilities > assets • N.C1* > N ! • → bank relies on type 2s not withdrawing.

  31. ‘Good’ outcome period 1 -- review. • Type 2s optimise by setting C12 = 0 • → Liquidity demand in period 1 is: • pNC1* + (1 – p)N.0 • = ½NC1* < N • ‘Bad’ outcome period 1: • All Type 2s fear run → Total liquidity demand: • ½NC1* + ½NC1* • = NC1* > N • Maximum proportion of depositors who can withdraw : • f = 1 / C1* • We have: C1* = 1 + π* • Substituting: 1 – f = (1 + π* – 1) / C1* = π* / C1* • i.e. Fraction who receive nothing is π* / C1*

  32. Intermediation and autarchy compared. • With and without a bank run. • Total expected utility of those who manage to withdraw deposits in presence of run: • N individuals. • Fraction who are paid is 1/C1*. • → E[U] = N.{1/C1*}.U(C1*)}

  33. Those who receive nothing have U[0], so total expected social utility is the same! • But can be expanded thus: • Fraction who receive nothing is π*/C1* • → E[SU] = N.{1/C1*.[U(C1*)] + π*/C1*.[U(0)]} • Note again: • We here have the utility of ALL individuals, lucky and unlucky: • 1/C1* + π*/C1* • = (1 + π*) / C1* • = C1* / C1* • = 1

  34. Individual’s expected utility / assumption of no bank run: • E[U] = ½[U(C1*) + U(C2*)] • Note: C2* > C1* → E[U] > U(C1*) • Comparing expected utility with run, we have: • With run: E[U] = 1/C1*.U(C1*) [ + 0 ] • 1/C1* < 1 • → E[U] < U(C1*) • From above, we have: • Without run: E[U] > U(C1*)

  35. Measures to prevent bank runs. • The ‘good’ and ‘bad’ outcomes: Nash equilibria: • Agents optimise autonomously. • Disregard effect of actions at aggregate level. • Strategy: Make ‘good’ Nash equilibrium unique. • Influence expectations / provide confidence. 3 possible solutions: • Action by banks themselves: Suspend convertibility • Government actions: Government-backed deposit insurance Lender of last resort facility

  36. Strategies to eliminate the ‘bad’ Nash equilibrium • (1) Suspension of convertibility. • Problem: Fragility of the contract: • Liquidation value of assets in period 1 is 1. • BUT: C1 = 1, and consequently C2 = R, is same as autarchy would provide anyway! • Thus: • Necessary condition for intermediary to offer improvement on autarchy is: • Must offer to pay out more than liquidation value of its assets in period 1!

  37. Advantage of suspension of liquidity: • Time for assets to be liquidated in orderly way • → better price than in ‘fire-sale’ conditions. • Bank announces: • Will suspend convertibility if pays out fraction (p = ½ ) of its deposit liabilities. • Consequences for Type 1s • Some left with 0 • Consequences for Type 2s • All assured of C2* in period 2

  38. Type 2s all assured of C2* in period 2 → gives them incentive to keep deposits till period 2. i.e. strategy for eliminating ‘bad’ equilibrium / threat of bank panic. → Counters risk of run. . .

  39. Strategies to eliminate the ‘bad’ Nash equilibrium • (2) Deposit insurance. • We now assume: • Government has imposed system of deposit insurance. • Equalises amount Type 1s and Type 2s can withdraw in period 1in the presence of run. • → None left with 0 through being at the back of the queue. • Advantage of government over bank in arranging deposit insurance: • Can use tax system to claw back funds from depositors after withdrawal of deposits.

  40. Number of Type 1s = number of Type 2s = ½ N • → Total number of desired withdrawals: • N (assuming all Type 2s panic → wish to set C22 = 0). • Total amount deposited = N • → Each can receive N/N = 1. • → E[U] = ½[U(1) + U(1)] • i.e. E[U] = U(1)

  41. Deposit insurance with run and autarchy ranked. • With bank run and deposit insurance, we have: • E[U] = ½[U(1) + U(1)] (i.e. U(1).) • Under autarchy, we have: • E[U] = ½[U(1) + U(R)] • R > 1 → Autarchy ‘ranks’ better in terms of social welfare. • Discrepancy: due to ‘premature liquidation effect’. • i.e. loss of return on the early withdrawals by Type 2s.

  42. Ranking E[U] with and without deposit insurance. • Question: Amount paid out same in each case, so SU same??? • Without insurance: • 1/C1* withdraw C1* • 1/π* are left with nothing. • ‘Unfair’! • With insurance: • No one gets more than 1. • At least this is ‘fair’!

  43. Answer: • Added utility to the successful of receiving C1* rather than 1 • outweighed by • Loss in utility by the unsuccessful • of receiving 0 rather than 1. • i.e. ‘Fairer’ distribution through insurance maximises social welfare subject to available resources. • i.e. Deposit insurance has reversed the ‘distribution effect’.

  44. If bank run develops, deposit insurance can motivate Type 2s not to withdraw. • Even though expected utility in period 2 no more than in period 1 • (1) E[U] in period 2 no worse than in period 1. • (2) Chance that run will not develop into a panic • → might get C2 > 1 after all.

More Related