1 / 32

Beyond selfish routing: Network Games

Beyond selfish routing: Network Games. Network Games. NGs model the various ways in which selfish users (i.e., players) strategically interact in using a network They aim to capture two competing issues for players: to minimize the cost they incur in creating/using the network

simpsons
Download Presentation

Beyond selfish routing: Network Games

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Beyond selfish routing:Network Games

  2. Network Games • NGs model the various ways in which selfish users (i.e., players) strategically interact in using a network • They aim to capture two competing issues for players: • to minimize the cost they incur in creating/using the network • to ensure that the network provides them with a high quality of service

  3. Motivations • NGs can be used to model: • formation of social network (edge represent social relations) • how subnetworks connect in computer networks • formation of P2P networks connecting users to each other for downloading files (local connection games) • how users try to share costs in using an existing network (global connection games)

  4. Setting • What is a stable network? • we use a NE as the solution concept • we refer to networks corresponding to Nash Equilibria as being stable • How to evaluate the overall quality of a network? • the social cost is given by the sum of players’ costs • Our goal: to bound the efficiency loss resulting from selfishness

  5. Our case study:Global Connection Games

  6. The model • G=(V,E): directed graph, k players • ce: non-negative cost of e E • Player i has a source node si and a sink node ti • Strategy for player i: a path Pi from si to ti • Let ke denote the number of users using edge e. The cost of Pi for player i in S=(P1,…,Pk) is shared with all the other players using (part of) it: costi(S) =  ce/ke ePi this cost-sharing scheme is called fair or Shapley cost-sharing mechanism

  7. The model • Given a strategy vector S, the constructed network N(S) is given by the union of all paths Pi • Then, the cost of the constructed network (social-choice function) is the following: • Notice that each user has a favorable effect on the performance of other users (so-called cross monotonicity), as opposed to the congestion model of selfish routing C(S)= costi(S) =  ce/ke=  ce ePi i i eN(S)

  8. Bounding the loss of efficiency • Remind that a network is optimal or socially efficient if it minimizes the social cost • We use the PoA to estimate the loss of efficiency we may have in the worst case, as given by the ratio between the cost of a worst stable network and the cost of an optimal network • What about the ratio between the costs of a best stable network and of an optimal network?

  9. Be optimist!: The price of stability (PoS) • Definition (Schulz & Moses, 2003): Given a game G and a social-choice minimization (resp., maximization) function C (i.e., the sum of all players’ payoffs), let S be the set of NE, and let OPT be the outcome of G optimizing C. Then, the Price of Stability (PoS) of G w.r.t. C is: PoSG(C) =

  10. Some remarks • PoA and PoS are (for positive s.c.f. C) •  1 for minimization problems •  1 for maximization problems • PoA and PoS are small when they are close to 1 • PoS is at least as close to 1 than PoA • In a game with a unique NE, PoA=PoS • Why to study the PoS? • sometimes a nontrivial bound is possible only for PoS • PoS quantifies the necessary degradation in quality under the game-theoretic constraint of stability

  11. An example 3 s2 1 3 1 1 3 1 2 s1 t2 t1 4 5.5

  12. An example 3 s2 1 3 1 1 3 1 2 s1 t2 t1 4 5.5 optimal network has cost 12 cost1=7 cost2=5 is it stable?

  13. An example 3 s2 1 3 1 1 3 1 2 s1 t2 t1 4 5.5 …no!, player 1 can decrease its cost cost1=5 cost2=8 …yes, and has cost 13! is it stable?  PoA  13/12, PoS ≤ 13/12

  14. An example 3 s2 1 3 1 1 3 1 2 s1 t2 t1 4 5.5 …a best possible NE: cost1=5 cost2=7.5 the social cost is 12.5  PoS = 12.5/12 Homework: find a worst possible NE

  15. Addressed issues in GCG • Does a stable network always exist? • Does the repeated version of the game always converge to a stable network? • How long does it take to converge to a stable network? • Can we bound the price of anarchy (PoA)? • Can we bound the price of stability (PoS)?

  16. Theorem 1 Any instance of the global connection game has a pure Nash equilibrium, and best response dynamic always converges. Theorem 2 The price of anarchy in the global connection game with k players is at most k. Theorem 3 The price of stability in the global connection game with k players is at most Hk, the k-th harmonic number.

  17. The potential function method For any finite game, an exact potential function is a function that maps every strategy vector S to some real value and satisfies the following condition: • S=(s1,…,sk), s’isi, let S’=(s1,…,s’i,…,sk), then (S)-(S’) = costi(S)-costi(S’). A game that does possess an exact potential function is called potential game

  18. Lemma 1 Every potential game has at least one pure Nash equilibrium, namely the strategy vector S that minimizes(S). Proof: consider any move by a player i that results in a new strategy vector S’. Since (S) is minimum, we have: (S)-(S’) = costi(S)-costi(S’)  0 player i cannot decrease its cost, thus S is a NE. costi(S)  costi(S’)

  19. Convergence in potential games Observation: any state S with the property that (S) cannot be decreased by altering any one strategy in S is a NE by the same argument. This implies the following: Lemma 2 In any finite potential game, best response dynamic always converges to a Nash equilibrium Proof:best response dynamic simulates local search on .

  20. …turning our attention to the global connection game… Let  be the following function mapping any strategy vector S to a real value [Rosenthal 1973]: (S) = eN(S) e(S) where (recall that ke is the number of players using e) e(S) = ce · H = ce · (1+1/2+…+1/ke). ke

  21. Lemma 3 ( is a potential function) Let S=(P1,…,Pk), let P’i be an alternative path for some player i, and define a new strategy vector S’=(S-i,P’i). Then: (S) - (S’) = costi(S) – costi(S’). Proof: • It suffices to notice that: • If edge e is used one more time in S: (S+e)=(S)+ce/(ke+1) • If edge e is used one less time in S: (S-e)=(S) - ce/ke • (S) -(S’) = (S) -(S-Pi+P’i) = (S)– ((S) - ePi ce/ke + eP’ice/(ke+1))= costi(S) – costi(S’).

  22. Existence of a NE Theorem 1 Any instance of the global connection game has a pure Nash equilibrium, and best response dynamic always converges. Proof:From Lemma 3, a GCG is a potential game, and from Lemma 1 and 2 best response dynamic converges to a pure NE.

  23. Price of Anarchy: a lower bound k s1,…,sk t1,…,tk 1 optimal network has cost 1  best NE: all players use the lower edge PoS is 1  worst NE: all players use the upper edge PoA is k

  24. k k k k     i=1 i=1 i=1 i=1 Upper-bounding the PoA Theorem 2 The price of anarchy in the global connection game with k players is at most k. Proof: Let OPT=(P1*,…,Pk*) denote the optimal network, and let i be a shortest path in G between si and ti. Let w(i) be the length of such a path, and let S be any NE. Observe that costi(S)≤w(i) (otherwise the player i would change). Then: C(S) = costi(S)≤ w(i)≤ w(Pi*)≤ k·costi(OPT) = k·C(OPT).

  25. PoS for GCG: a lower bound >o: small value t1,…,tk 1/k 1/(k-1) 1/3 1 1/2 sk-1 . . . s1 s2 s3 sk 1+ 0 0 0 0 0

  26. PoS for GCG: a lower bound >o: small value t1,…,tk 1/k 1/(k-1) 1/3 1 1/2 sk-1 . . . s1 s2 s3 sk 1+ 0 0 0 0 0 The optimal solution has a cost of 1+ is it stable?

  27. PoS for GCG: a lower bound >o: small value t1,…,tk 1/k 1/(k-1) 1/3 1 1/2 sk-1 . . . s1 s2 s3 sk 1+ 0 0 0 0 0 …no! player k can decrease its cost… is it stable?

  28. PoS for GCG: a lower bound >o: small value t1,…,tk 1/k 1/(k-1) 1/3 1 1/2 sk-1 . . . s1 s2 s3 sk 1+ 0 0 0 0 0 …no! player k-1 can decrease its cost… is it stable?

  29. PoS for GCG: a lower bound >o: small value t1,…,tk 1/k 1/(k-1) 1/3 1 1/2 sk-1 . . . s1 s2 s3 sk 1+ 0 0 0 0 0 The only stable network k social cost: C(S)=  1/j =Hk  ln k + 1 k-th harmonic number j=1

  30. Lemma 4 Suppose that we have a potential game with potential function , and assume that for any outcome S we have C(S)/A  (S)  B C(S) for some A,B>0. Then the price of stability is at most AB. Proof: Let S’ be the strategy vector minimizing  (i.e., S’ is a NE) Let S* be the strategy vector minimizing the social cost we have: C(S’)/A  (S’)  (S*)  B C(S*)  PoS ≤ C(S’)/C(S*) ≤ A·B.

  31. Lemma 5 (Bounding  ) For any strategy vector S in the GCG, we have: C(S)  (S)  Hk C(S). Proof:Indeed: (S) = eN(S) e(S) = eN(S) ce· Hke  (S)  C(S) = eN(S) ce and (S) ≤ Hk· C(S) = eN(S) ce· Hk.

  32. Upper-bounding the PoS Theorem 3 The price of stability in the global connection game with k players is at most Hk, the k-th harmonic number. Proof:From Lemma 3, a GCG is a potential game, and from Lemma 5 and Lemma 4 (with A=1 and B=Hk), its PoS is at most Hk.

More Related