570 likes | 586 Views
Explore the spectrum of market structures, including perfect competition, monopoly, and oligopoly, and understand the importance of strategic interaction in oligopolistic markets.
E N D
Finance 510: Microeconomic Analysis Strategic Interaction
Recall that there is an entire spectrum of market structures Market Structures • Perfect Competition • Many firms, each with zero market share • P = MC • Profits = 0 (Firm’s earn a reasonable rate of return on invested capital • NO STRATEGIC INTERACTION! • Monopoly • One firm, with 100% market share • P > MC • Profits > 0 (Firm’s earn excessive rates of return on invested capital) • NO STRATEGIC INTERACTION!
Most industries, however, don’t fit the assumptions of either perfect competition or monopoly. We call these industries oligopolies • Oligopoly • Relatively few firms, each with positive market share • STRATEGIC INTERACTION! Wireless (2002) Verizon: 30% Cingular: 22% AT&T: 20% Sprint PCS: 14% Nextel: 10% Voicestream: 6% US Beer (2001) Anheuser-Busch: 49% Miller: 20% Coors: 11% Pabst: 4% Heineken: 3% Music Recording (2001) Universal/Polygram: 23% Sony: 15% EMI: 13% Warner: 12% BMG: 8%
Further, these market shares are not constant over time! Airlines (1992) Airlines (2002) American American United United Delta Delta Northwest Northwest Continental Continental US Air SWest While the absolute ordering didn’t change, all the airlines lost market share to Southwest.
Another trend is consolidation Retail Gasoline (1992) Retail Gasoline (2001) Shell Exxon/Mobil Chevron Shell Texaco BP/Amoco/Arco Exxon Amoco Chev/Texaco Mobil Total/Fina/Elf BP Conoco/Phillips Citgo Marathon Sun Phillips
The key difference in oligopoly markets is that price/sales decisions can’t be made independently of your competitor’s decisions Your Price (-) Monopoly Oligopoly Your N Competitors Prices (+) Oligopolistic markets rely crucially on the interactions between firms which is why we need game theory to analyze them!
The Airline Price Wars Suppose that American and Delta face the given aggregate demand for flights to NYC and that the unit cost for the trip is $200. If they charge the same fare, they split the market $500 $220 American 60 180 What will the equilibrium be? Delta
The Airline Price Wars Assume that Delta has the following beliefs about American’s Strategy Probabilities of choosing High or Low price Player A’s best response will be his own set of probabilities to maximize expected utility
Subject to Probabilities always have to sum to one Both Prices have a chance of being chosen
The Airline Price Wars Both always charge $500 Both Randomize between $500 and $220 Both always charge $220 Notice that prices are low most of the time!
Continuous Choice Games – Cournot Competition There are two firms in an industry – both facing an aggregate (inverse) demand curve given by D Aggregate Production Both firms have constant marginal costs equal to $C
From firm one’s perspective, the demand curve is given by Treated as a constant by Firm One Solving Firm One’s Profit Maximization…
In Game Theory Lingo, this is Firm One’s Best Response Function To Firm 2 Note that this is the optimal output for a monopolist!
Further, if Firm two produces It drives price down to MC
The game is symmetric with respect to Firm two… Firm 1 Firm 2
Firm 1 Competitive Output Monopoly Output There exists a unique Nash equilibrium Firm 2
A numerical example… Suppose that the market demand for computer chips (Q is in millions) is given by Intel and Cyrix are both competing in the market and have a marginal cost of $20.
One more point… Monopoly Duopoly If both firms agreed to produce 1.25M chips (half the monopoly output), they could split the monopoly profits ($62.5 apiece). Why don’t these firms collude?
Suppose we increase the number of firms… Demand facing firm i is given by (MC = c)
Firm i’s best response to its N-1 competitors is given by Further, we know that all firms produce the same level of output. Solving for price and quantity, we get
Expanding the number of firms in an oligopoly • Note that as the number of firms increases: • Output approaches the perfectly competitive level of production • Price approaches marginal cost. Lets go back to the previous example…
Recall, we had an aggregate demand for computer chips and a constant marginal cost of production. CS = (.5)(120 – 53)(3.33) = $112 $112 $53 D What would it be worth to consumers to add another firm to the industry? 3.33
With three firms in the market… CS = (.5)(120 – 45)(3.75) = $140 $140 $45 D 3.75 A 25% increase in CS!!
Now, suppose that there were annual fixed costs equal to $10 How many firms can this industry support? Solve for N
The previous analysis was with identical firms. Firm 1 Suppose Firm 2’s marginal costs are greater than Firm 1’s…. Firm 2
Suppose Firm 2’s marginal costs are greater than Firm 1’s…. Firm 1 Firm 2 Firm 2’s market share drops
As long as average industry costs are the same as the identical firm case + Industry output and price are unaffected! Note, however, that production is undertaken in an inefficient manner! With constant marginal costs, the firm with the lower cost should be supplying the entire market!!
Market Concentration and Profitibility Industry Demand The Lerner index for Firm i is related to Firm i’s market share and the elasticity of industry demand The Average Lerner index for the industry is related to the HHI and the elasticity of industry demand
The previous analysis (Cournot Competition) considered quantity as the strategic variable. Bertrand competition uses price as the strategic variable. Should it matter? P* D Q* Just as before, we have an industry demand curve and two competing duopolists – both with marginal cost equal to c.
Cournot Case Bertrand Case D D
Price competition creates a discontinuity in each firm’s demand curve – this, in turn creates a discontinuity in profits As in the cournot case, we need to find firm one’s best response (i.e. profit maximizing response) to every possible price set by firm 2.
Firm One’s Best Response Function Case #1: Firm 2 sets a price above the pure monopoly price: Case #2: Firm 2 sets a price between the monopoly price and marginal cost Case #3: Firm 2 sets a price below marginal cost Case #4: Firm 2 sets a price equal to marginal cost What’s the Nash equilibrium of this game?
Bertrand Equilibrium: It only takes two firm’s in the market to drive prices to marginal cost and profits to zero! • However, the Bertrand equilibrium makes some very restricting assumptions… • Firms are producing identical products (i.e. perfect substitutes) • Firms are not capacity constrained
An example…capacity constraints Consider two theatres located side by side. Each theatre’s marginal cost is constant at $10. Both face an aggregate demand for movies equal to Each theatre has the capacity to handle 2,000 customers per day. What will the equilibrium be in this case?
If both firms set a price equal to $10 (Marginal cost), then market demand is 5,400 (well above total capacity = 2,000) Note: The Bertrand Equilibrium (P = MC) relies on each firm having the ability to make a crediblethreat: “If you set a price above marginal cost, I will undercut you and steal all your customers!” At a price of $33, market demand is 4,000 and both firms operate at capacity
Imperfect Substitutes Recall our previous model that included travel time in the purchase price of a product Length = 1 Customer Firm 1 Distance to Store Consumers places a value V on the product Travel Costs Dollar Price
Imperfect Substitutes Now, suppose that there are two competitors in the market – operating at the two sides of town Customer Firm 1 Firm 2 The “Marginal Consumer” is indifferent between the two competitors. We can solve for the “location” of this customer to get a demand curve
Imperfect Substitutes Customer Firm 1 Firm 2
Both firms have a marginal cost equal to c Each firm needs to choose price to maximize profits conditional on the other firm’s choice of price.
Bertrand Equilibrium with imperfect substitutes Firm 1 Firm 2
Cournot vs Bertrand Suppose that Firm two‘s costs increase. What happens in each case? Bertrand Cournot Firm 1 Firm 1 Firm 2 Firm 2
Cournot vs Bertrand Suppose that Firm two‘s costs increase. What happens in each case? • Cournot (Quantity Competition): Competition is very aggressive • Firm One responds to firm B’s cost increases by expanding production and increasing market share\ • Best response strategies are strategic substitutes Bertrand (Price Competition): Competition is very passive • Firm One responds to firm B’s cost increases by increasing price and maintaining market share • Best response strategies are strategic complements
Stackelberg leadership – Quantity Competition In the previous example, firms made price/quantity decisions simultaneously. Suppose we relax that and allow one firm to choose first. Both firms have a marginal cost equal to c Firm A chooses its output first Firm B chooses its output second Market Price is determined
Firm B has observed Firm A’s output decision and faces the residual demand curve: