1 / 55

Auction Theory

Auction Theory. Class 8 – Multi-unit auctions: part 1. Outline. Multi-unit auctions: goals and challenges Reminder: Walrasian equilibria The simultaneous ascending auction Definition Efficiency incentives Spectrum auction examples Weaknesses of the Simultaneous Ascending Auction.

roman
Download Presentation

Auction Theory

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Auction Theory Class 8 – Multi-unit auctions: part 1

  2. Outline • Multi-unit auctions: goals and challenges • Reminder: Walrasian equilibria • The simultaneous ascending auction • Definition • Efficiency • incentives • Spectrum auction examples • Weaknesses of the Simultaneous Ascending Auction

  3. The art of auction design • Mechanism design with multiple items is not well understood: • Multi-parameter mechanism design • Computational and communication complexity • Complex incentive structure • Bounded rationality of agents • Still an art, more than science. • But, based on theoretical and empirical knowledge.

  4. Multiple items • Goal: design auctions that allow for multiple kinds of items • Items are non identical. • Also known as “Combinatorial Auctions” • Examples: • Spectrum licenses. • Financial assets. • Transportation of packages. • Advertising campaigns • Industrial equipment. • Airport landing slots. • Bus routes. • Internet ads. • Privatization

  5. Leading Application: Spectrum Auctions • Adopted by the FCC in 1994. • Revolutionized the sale of spectrum. • Licenses are sold for specific frequencies in specific geographic areas. • Has been used since all over the world. • Also in UK, Germany, Netherlands, Canada, The Pacific, India, etc… • The basis of auctions for complex resource allocation problems. • Trigger for research

  6. Combinatorial preferences • Why shouldn’t we auction each item separately? • Auctioning each item alone ignores: • complements: v(TV) + v(VCR) < v(TV+VCR) • Substitutes:v(TV Toshiba) + v(TV Sony) > v(bothTVs) • Bidding for packages (or bundles) may increase the efficiency of the auction.

  7. Desired properties • What would be desirable properties of such auctions? • Auction finds “market clearing” prices. • In equilibrium... • Auction rules are simple. • Robust to collusion, false-name bids, timing manipulations, etc. • Tractable: ends in reasonable time, bidders can compute their equilibrium strategies. • Bidders should not be expected to process or to report large amounts of data.

  8. Challenges • Sealed-bid auctions? • Problematic. Bidder preferences may be complex. • Market-clearing prices may not exist • Especially when items are complements. • Bidders do not always know their preference… • Determining the preferences is often costly. • Do bidders know the equilibrium strategy in the complex auction?

  9. Computational complexity • The complex structure of multi-item auctions introduces technical problems: • Complexity of winner determination: hard for computers to compute the optimal allocation in a reasonable time • Such computational problems are called NP-hard. • Prevents, for example, the use of VCG in many settings. • Communication complexity: Private values to big to communicate. • Strategic complexity: bidders need to act quickly. Even if they are fully rational, computation (computer/ consultants etc) may be too slow to find the optimal strategy. • Solutions must take other considerations into account (incentive, for example) • Interdisciplinary field.

  10. Outline • Multi-unit auctions: goals and challenges • Reminder: Walrasian equilibria • The simultaneous ascending auction • Definition • Efficiency • incentives • Spectrum auction examples • Weaknesses of the Simultaneous Ascending Auction

  11. Demand • Bidders observe prices and determine their demand • Per-item prices are announced • Bidder decide what is the bundle that maximizes their surplus under these prices • (we all compute our demand. For example, when going to the supermarket.) • Formally:For a bidder i, and prices p1,…,pnwe say that the bundle T is a demand of i if for every other bundle S:

  12. Walrasian Equilibrium We would like to reach an outcome where the market clears. • A Walrasian equilibrium is an allocation S1,…,Snand item prices p1,…,pnsuch that: • Si is the demand of bidder i under the prices p1,…,pm • For any item j that is not allocated (not in S1,…,Sn) we have pj=0

  13. Efficiency of market-clearing prices The first welfare theorem:The allocation in a Walrasian equilibrium is efficient. • proof: consider another allocation, T1,…,Tn • For every bidder: • Summing over all bidders: The price of unallocated items is 0 S1,…,Snis efficient…

  14. Outline • Multi-unit auctions: goals and challenges • Reminder: Walrasian equilibria • The simultaneous ascending auction • Definition • Efficiency • incentives • Spectrum auction examples • Weaknesses of the Simultaneous Ascending Auction

  15. Objective Seller’s goal: maximize efficiency By law for FCC spectrum auctions.

  16. Eliciting the preferences How can we run an auction for m items? Direct revelation? Each bidder has to report vi(S) exponential size More than million values with only 20 items. The common solution: iterative auctions. Seller can define a set of questions/queries: How much are you willing to pay for the bundle S? Would you buy the bundle S for $5000? Ask the bidders for the demand under the current prices, and then update the prices. “Ascending-price auctions”. One hopes that iterative auctions would require less communication.

  17. Ascending-price auctions Initial prices are announces. Prices can only go up. • Revenue considerations: • It is widely believed that ascending auctions gain more revenue than other methods • Rule of thumb, but supported by empirical data and some theory.

  18. Why ascending-price auctions? Simple and intuitive for bidders Terminates (relatively) quickly “Price discovery” – directs the attention of the bidders to the relevant items. No need to determine the value of the other items/bundles. For example: if they see an aggressive competition on one item, which become expensive, they may let it go. Easier to assemble “packages” of items. Decreases the amount of information broadcasted. Again, bidders bid only on items that turn out to be relevant.

  19. Simultaneous Ascending Auction • The prevalent auction for spectrum auctions. • And other multi-item auctions (Google’s TV, transportation, etc.) • Suggested to the FCC for the spectrum auctions in 1994 • By Milgrom, McAfee, and Wilson • Main ideas: • Simultaneous • Ascending • Item prices • Stopping rule • Activity rule

  20. Simultaneous Ascending Auction Intuitively, the simultaneous ascending auction works as follows: • Start with zero prices. • Each bidder reports her favorite bundle (“demand”) • Provisional winners are announced. • Price of over-demanded items is raised by ε. • Stop when there are no over-demanded items. • i.e., Walrasian equilibrium is reached.

  21. Simultaneous Ascending Auction For formally proving the properties of the auction, we will need to define it more formally.

  22. Simultaneous Ascending Auction Before starting: - pj=0 for every item j. - Temporary bundle Si is empty. Repeat the following process: • Let Di be a demand of bidder i under these prices: • pj+ε for items in Si • pj for all other items • If for all bidders Si=Di, stop the auction. • Otherwise, find a bidder i with Si ≠ Diand update: • For items j in Di but not in Si, set pj=pj+ ε • Si=Di • for every bidder k ≠i, Sk=Sk\Di(that is, remove the items in Di) The final outcome: Allocation S1,….,Snand prices p1,…., pn Collect demand Update provisional winners and raise prices

  23. Simultaneous Ascending Auction • Theorem: when all bidders have substitutes valuations, the simultaneous ascending auction terminates at a Walrasian equilibrium. • Therefore, at an efficient outcome. • Up to an ε • Based on literature by Kelso and Crawford (1982), Demange, Gale and Sotomayor (1986), Gul and Stacchetti(1999), Milgrom (2000)

  24. Substitutes • The economic intuition: if a,b are substitutes and the price of a increases, then the bidder still demands b. • Formal definition:Consider prices p1,…,pmand prices q1,…,qmwhere some of the prices are increased.For every demand Ai of bidder i under prices p1,…,pm, bidder i demands a bundle Di under the prices q1,…,qnthat contains all the items in Ai that their prices were not changed. • (Think about the case where the demand is a unique bundle. Quantifiers in the definition handle the case of multiple demand)

  25. Substitutes: examples $3 $7 $1 $10 $8 • The following valuations satisfy the substitutes condition: • Additive: there is a value attached to each item, and the value of a bundle is the sum of the values of the item in it.V( ) = 3 + 1 + 10 = 14 • Unit demand: bidder have value per each item, but want at most one item • The value of a bundle is the maximal value of an item in it. • V( ) = max{ 3, 1, 10 } = 10

  26. Proof • The theorem follows from the following lemma: • Lemma: At every stage of the auction, and for every bidder i, • Proof: By induction. (Clearly holds at the beginning.) • Assume (*) holds, and we will show it still holds after the update. • Consider bidder i that is selected at stage 2: • After the updating, we have Si=Di. • Consider bidder k ≠ i: • Two changes can occur: • If items were taken from Sk byi, Sk became smaller and (*) still holds. • If prices of items not in Sk were increased, due to the substitutes property the only items that can be removed now are items whose prices were increased. (But those were taken to i.) (*)

  27. Simultaneous Ascending Auction • Theorem: when all bidders have substitutes valuations, the simultaneous ascending auction terminates at a Walrasian equilibrium. • Therefore, at an efficient outcome. • Up to an ε • We will conclude the theorem from the lemma: • Every item with non-zero price was allocated to one of the bidders. • From this point on, it was demanded by at least one of the bidders. • At the end, all demanded items are allocated – Walrasian equilibrium.

  28. Walrasian equilibrium • We actually proved: with substitutes valuations, Walrasian equilibrium always exists. • Constructive proof: it is reached by the ascending-price auctions. • However, Walrasianequilibria do not always exist.

  29. Walrasian eq. does not always exist • Consider the following valuations: Claim: there is no Walrasian equilibrium for these preferences. Why? • What is the efficient allocation? • Bob gets both items. • Alice should demand nothing in any Walrasian equilibrium. • Price of both items should be at least 2 • But then Bob will not demand {a,b}.

  30. Outline • Multi-unit auctions: goals and challenges • Reminder: Walrasian equilibria • The simultaneous ascending auction • Definition • Efficiency • incentives • Spectrum auction examples • Weaknesses of the Simultaneous Ascending Auction

  31. Incentives • In the analysis we assumed that bidders bid “straightforward” bidding: bid their actual demand at each stage. • Will they? Is the SSA truthful? • For substitutes preferences. • Answer:no. Reason: Bidders can benefit from “demand reduction”. • Nevertheless: variants of this auction are used successfully in many environments.

  32. Profitable Demand reduction • Consider the following substitutes preferences: • SSA auction terminates with a Walrasian equilibrium: pa=4, pb=4 and Bob wins {a,b}. • Bob’s payoff: 2 • If Bob strategically reduces his demand to a only: auction stops at pa=pb=0. Bob wins a, Alice wins b. • Bob’s payoff: 5 !

  33. Unit-demand preferences • However, the simultaneous ascending auction is incentive compatible for a sub-family of substitutes preferences: unit-demand valuations. • Each bidder wants at most one item (but items are still non-identical) • Non identical items: a, b, c, d, e, • Each bidder has a value for each itemvi(a),vi(b),bi(c),..

  34. Example • Let’s run the SSA auction with the following valuations.

  35. VCG and Walrasian equilibrium Actually it is known that VCG prices are the lowest Walrasian equilibrium for such preferences. That is, least preferable to the seller. Conclusion: Truthful behavior is an equilibrium in the auction. (Any deviation leads to a non-optimal outcome) • Theorem: for unit-demand valuations • The VCG outcome is a Walrasian equilibrium • The SSA terminates at VCG prices

  36. Example • What is the VCG outcome? • What is the efficient allocation? • VCG payment for Bidder 1? • Without Bidder 1, others gain 13. • With him, they gain 10. • p1=3 Similarly, p2=0, p3=3.

  37. Outline • Multi-unit auctions: goals and challenges • Reminder: Walrasian equilibria • The simultaneous ascending auction • Definition • Efficiency • incentives • Spectrum auction examples • Weaknesses of the Simultaneous Ascending Auction

  38. Auction examples Let’s consider some positive and negative examples for spectrum auctions. We will see some consideration that do not appear in our formal model.

  39. The UK 2000 spectrum auction In 2000, the UK government ran an auction for selling spectrum licenses for 3G wireless services. Government declared objectives: Maximize efficiency Promote competition Increases value for customers and tax-payers. First time an auction is use to allocate spectrum in the UK. Details from one of the economists involved in this auction:Peter Cramton http://www.cramton.umd.edu/papers2000-2004/01nao-cramton-report-on-uk-3g-auction.pdf

  40. The UK 2000 spectrum auction The first important decision by the UK government: what to sell? 4 or 5 licenses? A license: grants right to use the spectrum + obligation to build a network with sufficient coverage. 4 incumbent 2G wireless companies in the UK at that time Vodafone, Orange, 1-2-1, , British Telecom. (But Vodafone was trying to take over Orange.) Incumbents have much higher values than new entrants (e.g., current infrastructure, 2G revenue loss is incurred if failed to secure 3G services)

  41. The UK 2000 spectrum auction Challenge: design an auction to attract other bidders to promote competition. Selling 4 licenses: With four big incumbents, other bidders may stay out. Without more bidders, prices will be very low Selling 5 licenses: Is it reasonable to build 5 separate networks? May hurt efficiency. May earn less revenue: the marginal value of the 6th bidder may be significantly lower. Main uncertainties: Who is the strongest new entrant? Who is the strongest incumbent (Vodafone or BT)?

  42. The UK 2000 spectrum auction Government decides to sell 5 licenses: Bandwidths: A (35) ,B (30) ,C (25) ,D (25) ,E (25) License A was reserved to a new entrant. Auction is simpler than the US auctions. Bidders can win at most one license. SSA is efficient and incentive compatible for unit-demand bidders. No geographic complexity (all licenses are nationwide)

  43. The UK 2000 spectrum auction The auction: A simultaneous ascending auction. All licenses are simultaneously on sale Bidding in rounds. Full transparency: After each round, all bids and bidders were identified. Minimum bids: percentage of previous bids (5% at the beginning, then 1.5%) Activity rule: bidders must either be current winners, or place bids. Each bidder has 3 waivers to spend. Bidders can also call for a recess and stop all bidding until next day, up to twice per each bidder). No bid withdrawal.

  44. The UK 2000 spectrum auction Outcome: 13 bidders in the auction (4 incumbents + 9 others, including big international companies) 150 rounds. Winners: 1 new entrant, 4 incumbents Auction raised $39 Billion Dollars (!!) “Largest auction in History” Prices exceeded everyone’s expectations. High prices: mainly set by BT (losing the big license) and NTL (the strongest losing bidder)

  45. The UK 2000 spectrum auction

  46. The UK 2000 spectrum auction Why high prices? Mainly set by BT (losing the big license) and NTL (the strongest losing bidder) The decision to sell 5 licenses attracted new entrants that raised the bidding levels. Setting aside a license for a new bidder added to this incentive. Winner’s curse on license A: 9 new entrants competing for it. Ascending auction format: Not raising is a confession of inferiority. “If the license is worth a lot for my competitor, why not to me?” Auction took seven weeks: enough time to go to the board and ask for more money… Specific environement: Auction held at the peak of the internet bubble. Auction was a first of a series of auctions: all large companies participated.

  47. The UK 2000 spectrum auction Strategies: Vodafone was bidding exclusively on the B license. The only large license available for incumbents. Often use “jump bids” to express its focus on the B license. Orange was bidding exclusively on E After B became too expensive.

  48. The Netherlands spectrum auction Let’s compare the UK 3G spectrum auction outcome to a one held in the Netherlands. Following the auction in the UK, the government decided to sell 5 licenses. Incumbents in the Netherlands: Five 2G operators Bidding partnership is allowed. Outcome?

  49. The Netherlands spectrum auction Outcome: Before the auction started, all major international firms had a partnership with a local incumbent. Only one potential new entrant was left (“Versatel”) On the first day, one big (joint) player sent Versatel a letter: “you can’t win, you should drop out immediately”. Soon after, Versatel drops out. Revenue: 3 Billion Euros. (under UK prices, estimated revenue should have been 10 Billion). • A conclusion: sell more licenses than the number of incumbents.

  50. The Netherlands spectrum auction One conclusion: sell more licenses than the number of incumbents.

More Related