1 / 37

The Efficiency of Markets and the Costs of Taxation

This text explores the concepts of price ceilings and price floors, consumer and producer surplus, market efficiency, and the effects of taxation on welfare and deadweight loss. It discusses the trade-offs between efficiency and equity and provides examples of different tax policies.

rloving
Download Presentation

The Efficiency of Markets and the Costs of Taxation

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. 6 The Efficiency of Markets and the Costs of Taxation

  2. Previously • A price ceiling is a legal maximum price. • A price floor is a legal minimum price. • If binding, these price controls don’t allow the market to reach equilibrium. • Shortages or surpluses will be the result.

  3. Big Questions • What are consumer surplus and producer surplus? • When is a market efficient? • Why do taxes create deadweight loss?

  4. Consumer and Producer Surplus Consumer surplus graphically: The height of the demand curve is our maximum willingness to pay for that unit of the good. Consumer surplus is the area below the demand curve and above the price, for all units purchased. Important concept: You can only get consumer surplus on units that you actually buy! CS is NOT the entire area under the demand curve.

  5. Consumer and Producer Surplus Producer surplus graphically: The height of the supply curve is the firm’s lowest price it is willing to accept to sell that unit of the good. Producer surplus is the area above the supply curve and below the price, for all units sold. Important concept: The firm can only get producer surplus on units that it actually sells! PS is NOT the entire area above the supply curve.

  6. Market Efficiency • Total surplus (or social welfare) measures the overall welfare of the society. • Total surplus = CS + PS • In free markets with voluntary trade: • Consumers buy until their willingness to pay is equal to the market price. • Suppliers sell until their willingness to sell is equal to the market price. • Efficiency • Occurs when total surplus is maximized in a market

  7. CS and PS for a Gallon of Milk

  8. The Efficiency Equity Debate • In free markets, both parties of self-interested individuals will benefit from trade. • Benefits might not be equal. Is that a problem? • Efficiency asks: • Are the gains from trade maximized? Is economic welfare maximized? • Equity asks: • Are the benefits divided fairly?

  9. Taxation, Welfare, and Deadweight Loss • Why do we pay taxes? • Pay for public goods, police, roads, schools, etc. • Types of taxes • Income, payroll, corporate, sales, excise, estate • Excise tax • A tax on a specific good; alcohol, tobacco, gasoline, for example • Tax incidence • Refers to the party (consumers or producers) who bears the tax burden

  10. Tax on Buyers

  11. Tax on Sellers

  12. End Result • If a tax is levied on a business: • The firm will attempt to raise prices to pass some of the burden to consumers. • If a tax is levied on consumers: • Some of the burden is passed to producers since the market price falls. • Incidence • Whether the tax is levied on the producer or consumer, the end incidence result is the same!

  13. Deadweight Loss • On the previous graphs, the tax had a price and quantity effect. • Prices increased. • Quantity traded decreased. • Deadweight loss: • A cost to society in the form of less economic welfare resulting from the tax. • Caused by the decrease in the amount of trade that is occurring.

  14. Deadweight Loss, Graphically

  15. Tax and Deadweight Loss with Inelastic Demand • Tax incidence is the same no matter who the tax is levied on. • Elasticity of demand and supply can change tax incidence, though. • Why would the government want to tax a good with very inelastic demand? • No substitutes (ensures steady tax revenue) • Amount of purchases will not change much (or not change at all if perfectly inelastic demand) • This means little or no deadweight loss!

  16. Tax and Deadweight Loss with Perfectly Inelastic Demand

  17. Tax and Deadweight Loss with Somewhat Elastic Demand

  18. Tax and Deadweight Loss with Perfectly Elastic Demand

  19. Balancing Deadweight Loss and Tax Revenues • Must ask: What is the purpose of tax? • Gain tax revenues? • Decrease production or consumption of good (perhaps to reduce negative externalities)? • Ireland, 2002 • 15 cent tax on plastic bags • Purpose was to curb litter, encourage recycling • Plastic bag use fell by 90%.

  20. Realistic Example

  21. Excise Tax Summary • The total welfare is the same, whether a tax is levied on the consumer or the producer. • A tax on a good with inelastic demand or supply generates the maximum amount of revenue. • The deadweight loss of a tax is larger when demand and supply are more elastic. • The incidence of a tax is determined by the relative balance between the elasticity of supply and the elasticity of demand.

  22. Smoking Tax vs. Smoking Ban Why would we ever tax a good if it reduces efficiency in the market by creating deadweight loss? Two possible reasons to tax a good: Raise tax revenues to fund a public service Decrease production/consumption of that good How could we decrease smoking most effectively? Public smoking bans High cigarette taxes?

  23. Smoking Tax vs. Smoking Ban Public smoking bans: Cigarette prices remain the same. Substitute of “smoking at home” available Unintended consequence of more children exposed to secondhand smoke Cigarette taxes Taxes would have to be very high (inelastic demand). High enough taxes would decrease smoking everywhere and generate large tax revenues.

  24. Deadweight Loss and Tax Revenue

  25. Deadweight Loss and Tax Revenue

  26. Deadweight Loss and Tax Revenue

  27. Deadweight Loss and Tax Revenue

  28. Balancing DWL and Tax Revenues • Intuition: • If tax rates are too low or too high, revenue will be low. • There is an optimal tax rate to be found. • Later in the course: • The Laffer curve will be discussed. • This is the parabolic relationship between tax rates and tax revenue.

  29. Conclusion • Consumer and producer surplus can be used to examine any economic activity. • Unregulated markets create the largest possible total surplus. • Taxation is not a costless endeavor. The taxation of specific goods and services gives rise to deadweight loss, which results in the reduction of economic activity. • Society must balance the need for tax revenues, the programs those revenues fund, and trade-offs this creates in the market.

  30. Summary • Total surplus (social welfare) is the combined benefits that all members of society enjoy from undertaking an activity. • Total surplus= CS + PS • Markets maximize consumer and producer surplus, provide goods and services to buyers who value them most, and reward sellers who can produce goods and services at the lowest cost. • As a result, markets create the largest amount of social welfare possible.

  31. Summary • Whenever an allocation of resources maximizes total surplus, the result is said to be efficient. • “Equity” refers to the fairness of the distribution of the benefits among the members of a society. • Efficiency does not imply equity.

  32. Summary • Deadweight lossis the cost to society created by tax inefficiencies. • The amount of revenue a tax generates is maximized when the good that is taxed is inelastic. • The Laffer curve provides a limit on the expansion of taxation. • Tax revenues peek at moderate rates, where the trade-off from higher taxes is exactly offset by the loss of economic activity.

  33. Practice What You Know The height of the demand curve at any quantity can be thought of as the ___________. willingness to buy willingness to sell consumer surplus producer surplus

  34. Practice What You Know The difference between the price the good was sold at and the minimum price the firm would have accepted for the good is called willingness to sell. product markup. producer surplus. price-cost margin.

  35. Practice What You Know Deadweight loss can be thought of as surplus that is transferred from producers or consumers and given to __________. the government competitors in other markets taxpayers nobody

  36. Practice What You Know If the government wants to create tax revenues without generating any deadweight loss, what type of good should they tax? a good with a perfectly elastic demand a good with a relatively elastic demand a good with a perfectly inelastic demand a good with a relatively inelastic demand

  37. Practice What You Know According to the Laffer curve, increasing tax rates will always increase tax revenue. could increase or decrease tax revenue. will always decrease tax revenue. will never change tax revenues.

More Related