1 / 24

Approaches to Facilitating the Development Of Price-Responsive Demand Robert Earle Ahmad Faruqui

Approaches to Facilitating the Development Of Price-Responsive Demand Robert Earle Ahmad Faruqui Sam Newell The Brattle Group October 22, 2008. Agenda. I. Premise II. Approaches to Facilitating Price-Responsive Demand III. Integration of Approaches with Wholesale Market Design

pomona
Download Presentation

Approaches to Facilitating the Development Of Price-Responsive Demand Robert Earle Ahmad Faruqui

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Approaches to Facilitating the Development Of Price-Responsive Demand Robert Earle Ahmad Faruqui Sam Newell The Brattle Group October 22, 2008

  2. Agenda • I. Premise • II. Approaches to Facilitating Price-Responsive Demand • III. Integration of Approaches with Wholesale Market Design • IV. Advantages and Disadvantages of Each Approach • V. Conclusions

  3. Premise • New England can benefit from Price Responsive Demand (PRD) • Can make energy markets more competitive, compared to inelastic demand • Achieves efficiencies by making consumption/production decisions and pricing better reflect both the marginal value and marginal cost of power • Could reduce the need for administrative market mitigation and price caps • Reduces the need for generation capacity • The Challenge for New England • How to increase the amount of PRD to its economic potential and integrate it into the DA/RT energy markets more efficiently?

  4. Agenda • I. Premise • II. Approaches to Facilitating Price-Responsive Demand • III. Integration of Approaches with Wholesale Market Design • IV. Advantages and Disadvantages of Each Approach • V. Conclusions

  5. There are a variety of approaches to providing PRD: a taxonomy • Direct Load Control (DLC) • Customer end uses are directly controlled by the utility and are shut down (or reduced) during emergencies • Air conditioning DLC is presently a popular approach • Applies to residential and C&I classes • Typically thought of as useful for reliability DR programs, but can also be used for PRD (aka, economic DR) • Indirect Load Control (ILC) • Customer end use controlled by the customer but given a signal by a third party provider (aka, CSP in PJM) • Interruptible Service • Customers agree to reduce consumption to a pre-specified level, or by a pre-specified amount, in emergencies • Applies only to C&I class • Dynamic Pricing • Includes time-varying rates that can be called upon during emergencies or high-priced hours to encourage reductions in peak loads • At the very least, interval meters and a communication system must be in place to offer these rates. Examples include Critical Peak Pricing (CPP) and Real Time Pricing (RTP) • Advanced metering infrastructure (AMI) is the leading choice for implementing dynamic pricing • Applies to residential and C&I classes • Likely the wave of the future – RTOs will need to address the integration of PRD into wholesale market design • Recent CPUC decision will make dynamic pricing the default rates in California

  6. The motivation for dynamic rates • For most utilities, the top 100 hours of the year can account for more than 10 percent of system peak demand and can be very costly to serve • For ISO-NE, the top 100 hours are 13% of peak • 10% of the peak in ISO-NE occurs in 60 hours • Innovation in utility rate design seeks to lower costs and improve system efficiencies by targeting this critical-peak load • Traditional retail rate designs fail to accomplish the objective • Customers are unaware of the dynamic cost of providing electricity (no connection between flat retail rates and varying wholesale prices) • Non-time varying rates leading to over-consumption during peak periods • Even time-of-use (TOU) rates, while time varying, do not differentiate between regular peak hours and the highest cost hours of the year • But the majority of benefits of dynamic rates occur in the small number of critical peak hours • Dynamic pricing provides price signals that can vary as the system needs vary

  7. This results in a menu of innovative rate designs New (Dynamic) Rates Critical Peak Pricing (CPP) Peak Time Rebate (PTR) CPP-Variable (CPP-V) Variable Peak Pricing (VPP) Real Time Pricing (RTP) Existing Rates Flat Rate Inverted Tier (Blocks) Seasonal Time-of-day (TOD)

  8. Two Leading Approaches are CPP and PTR • Dynamic rates such as CPP and PTR provide demand response during peak conditions, which can result in short-term and long-term savings • Critical Peak Pricing • When the power system encounters critical conditions, the peak-period price rises to much higher but known levels, either on a day-ahead or day-of basis • Could be structured as CPP plus TOU (a CPP rate, a peak rate, and off-peak rate) or pure CPP (a CPP rate and an off-peak rate) • Peak Time Rebate • Customers stay on their current retail rate • Customers receive rebates for kWh reductions during critical peak events • The rebate is equal to the difference between the critical peak rate or the real-time price in the wholesale market and the “current” retail rate • The reduction in consumption during critical peak events must be calculated from a “baseline” consumption level

  9. Illustration of a CPP Rate • Critical peak and off-peak prices should reflect system costs • Revenue neutral • 10-20 critical days during summer, 4-6 hours per critical event (60-120 hours total) • Can also be layered on a TOU rate or an inverted tier rate

  10. The PTR is an inverse CPP rate

  11. A key challenge for integrating dynamic retail prices into an RTO wholesale market involves the LSE callable structures • Some pricing structures are static and will influence the load forecast, but little else: • Prices are known ahead of time • TOU Influences pattern of consumption, but not dynamically • Other pricing structures are dynamic, but not callable by the LSE, e.g., real time retail rates • Prices not known until day ahead or real time – or in some designs after the fact • Influences pattern of consumption dynamically, but LSE simply passes the prices on • Affects the RTO’s load forecast • There are other forms of RTP where callability is possible • LSE callable structures involve: • The LSE calling an “event” • End-user’s prices changing as a result of that event • CPP, PTR • Does LSE callability mean RTO dispatchability?

  12. Agenda • I. Premise • II. Approaches to Facilitating Price-Responsive Demand • III. Integration of Approaches with Wholesale Market Design • IV. Advantages and Disadvantages of Each Approach • V. Conclusions

  13. Available Approaches to PRD • PRD can occur in three ways (along the lines of our previous business models): • 1. No institutional involvement of the RTO (“No Curves”) • Consumption is reduced in response to high prices (or anticipated high prices) • Australia is an extreme example of this where demand bids are vertical • Less benefit than integration into the wholesale market because price elasticity of demand effects are indirect, not direct • Not recommended as an option for RTOs to rely on – included for completeness • 2. RTO has mechanisms for bidding of PRD through demand curves (“Demand Curves”) • The ability to submit sloped demand curves into the day-ahead energy market allows for this • However, characteristics of the particular dynamic retail rate program and the RTO’s market rules must be matched up • Example: If the notification time for a retail day-ahead dynamic price program occurs before market close, then integration of that retail program into a day-ahead demand bid is not possible • 3. RTO makes payments to customers for reducing load (“Supply Curves”) • Necessitates creation of uplift in order to fund payments • Creates baseline issues

  14. In theory, most dynamic retail rate programs could be integrated into RTOs • The question is: what accommodation/facilitation will have to be made, and will it be worth it? Let’s work through the issues with a specific example • Dynamic pricing in the form of critical peak pricing (CPP) or the like may likely be one of the greatest sources of PRD in the medium to long term • CPP typically consists of a base rate with 12 to 15 critical peak events that can be called during the year (usually restricted to summer months) • During those critical peak events, the price to end users rises and consumption falls

  15. CPP under the “No Curves” Approach • Without facilitation on the part of the RTO, CPP can be used by the LSE to mitigate high prices • Call events when the LSE thinks prices are going to be high • Standard valuation methods exist to facilitate this • Buy less from markets/sell more of long position • This method does not maximize the usefulness of PRD • Doesn’t translate directly into demand elasticity in the RTO market • LSE must guess what prices are going to be – no direct interaction or price triggers • No ability to set prices (though this ability may be limited under other approaches as well) • To what degree will calling CPP events affect the predictability of load and, therefore, reliability/operating reserves/imbalance markets?

  16. CPP under the “Demand Curves” Approach • Incorporating CPP as part of the demand curve bid would allow the LSE to set a reservation price for when it calls critical peak days • Set reservation price to reflect value of the call • Similar methods to evaluate when to call events as with the “No Curves” approach • Allows demand elasticity to play directly in the RTO market and perhaps let demand set the price • Translates into some amount of load reduction • The amount of load reduction is not likely to be exact due to varying end-user responsiveness • Is the inexactness of response analogous to wind? • Would need coordination with RTO on timing/locational issues/imbalance settlement • Program design at the end-user level would enhance usefulness at the RTO • Ability to call in blocks • Ameliorate locational issues • Not have to use resource as “all-or-nothing” • Timing of announcement of calls • Enabling technology would not only increase response, but likely stabilize it

  17. CPP under the “Supply Curves” Approach • Paying LSEs for load reductions by calling a critical day as part of a CPP program would also allow the LSE to set a reservation price for when it calls critical peak days • The characteristics of the Supply Curves Approach is similar to the Demand Curves approach • Scheduling issues are generally the same • However, the primary differences on the end-user program design level is that the CPP program would require customer baseline (CBL) measurement • Don’t need a CBL for CPP if one of the first two approaches (i.e., No Curves or Demand Curves) are used • At the RTO level, the issues include: • Verification of CBL • Level of payments for the reduction

  18. Agenda • I. Premise • II. Approaches to Facilitating Price-Responsive Demand • III. Integration of Approaches with Wholesale Market Design • IV. Advantages and Disadvantages of Each Approach • V. Conclusions

  19. Summary of Advantages and Disadvantages • Dynamic pricing likely has the greatest resource potential for PRD and can work with all of the approaches (no curves, demand curves, supply curves). Except for a few leading programs and some pilots, however, it is only slowly beginning to take off. Barriers are: • Reluctance on the part of state regulators to expose all but largest customers to volatile prices. • Need AMI to provide interval data and 2-way communication for small customers. • In the absence of widespread dynamic pricing, various wholesale programs have been developed to enable the marketing of “negawatts” (supply curves) as a “no lose” way to expose customers on fixed rates to market prices at the margin • Approaches include LSEs offering DLC negawatts into RT markets, CSPs offering DLC (and indirectly controlled) negawatts into RT markets as self-scheduled or dispatchable, similar to large wholesale customers. DA participation is rare. • ISO must facilitate through programs that provide for: • Incorporation of DR negawatts into scheduling, dispatch, and settlement systems, similar to generation • Need to accommodate diversity of characteristics (e.g., MDT, intermittency, block loading) • No DR sets RT prices in other RTOs due to lack to telemetry, zonal prices, uncertain customer baseline until after-the-fact • Baseline methodology (sometimes performed by CSPs or distribution utilities) • Funding mechanism (i.e., LSE or all customers pay gross), sometimes including a subsidy • Unless customers have a way to take title to their baseline usage, negawatt approaches may not be the best option • Baselines are subject to gaming and uncertainty • Side-payments from other customers to fund payments to negawatts questioned if baseline is uncertain

  20. Key Issues in Facilitating PRD • The “No Curves” approach basically leaves PRD outside the market • Requires nothing be done at the ISO! • “Demand Curves” and “Supply Curves” approaches share some issues: • Price setting • Dispersed response at the retail level requires aggregation on a zonal- rather than a nodal-basis, resulting in issues with setting LMP • Block loaded resources • Variability of reaction • Response amount is not exact for either DLC or pricing programs • In the California Statewide Pricing Project, confidence intervals range from ±6% to ±18% depending on pricing program • Issues with imbalance payments/penalties • Is demand response analogous to wind in this regard? • Conformation of bidding rules to program characteristics and timing

  21. Key Issues with the Supply Curves Approach • Double payments and the price formation problem – as presented by Dr. Chao • PJM has attempted to avoid this by only paying the difference between LMP and retail rate • This approach is plausible if the retail rate is known, but where there is retail choice this may be difficult • Customer base line issues – theory described by Dr. Chao • AKA, Measurement & Verification • Supply curves approaches require estimation of a customer baseline (PTR, for example)

  22. AMI Infrastructure Issues • Enabling dynamic pricing through AMI has costs • Most of the benefit from AMI comes through operational benefits • Existing infrastructure may be an issue Summary of California Utility AMI Costs Notes: Figures are rough estimates based on information in utility filings PG&E costs include initial $1.7 billion investment and $0.6 billion upgrade PG&E customers includes 5 million electric and 4 million gas customers Net cost calculation assumes 65% of costs are offset by operational benefits

  23. Agenda • I. Premise • II. Approaches to Facilitating Price-Responsive Demand • III. Integration of Approaches with Wholesale Market Design • IV. Advantages and Disadvantages of Each Approach • V. Conclusions

  24. Develop Vision of Endgame • Initial vision, subject to revision: • Every customer segment should provide price-responsive demand primarily through dynamic rates (very efficient and avoids awkward baseline/M&V issues) • Enable dynamic rates to be schedulable day-ahead through demand bids • Enable demand response that can be dispatched in RT (such as DLC) • To the extent feasible, enable price setting by price-responsive demand • May have to restrict to large customers depending on feasibility of overcoming difficulties for smaller customers • Smaller customers are dispersed • Explore how to make negawatts (supply curve approach) more cost effective and more useful

More Related