1 / 38

Measuring Benefits

Measuring Benefits. How much pollution is too much?. National Center for Environmental Economics USEPA. Repository of technical expertise regarding benefit and cost analysis. Types of Benefits of Environmental Policies. Human health Reduced risk of death Reduced risk of sickness

Download Presentation

Measuring Benefits

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Measuring Benefits How much pollution is too much?

  2. National Center for Environmental Economics USEPA • Repository of technical expertise regarding benefit and cost analysis

  3. Types of Benefits of Environmental Policies • Human health • Reduced risk of death • Reduced risk of sickness • Ecological improvements • Marketed products (food, fuel, fiber, timber) • Recreational activities • Ecosystem functions (climate moderation, biodiversity) • Nonuse values (aka existence values; specie and ecosystem specific) • Aesthetic improvements • Reduced damages to materials (soiling, corrosion)

  4. Benefits and channels of impacts

  5. Environmental Risk and Human Health • ‘Risk’ exists when one can assign a probability to the chance that an event will occur. • Two elements to environmental risk: • The probability of an unfavorable event, and • The severity of the event if realized.

  6. Environmental Risk • Overall risk assessment of a pollutant: actual risk to exposed individuals (probability) * number of people exposed. • Low risk pollutants may have a high risk assessment if many people are exposed. • High risk pollutants may rank low if few people are exposed.

  7. Relative environmental risks (EPA)

  8. Risk aversion • Most people are risk averse: a risk averse person is more likely to choose a certain payoff over a fair bet. • For the risk averse, a potential gain in income does not create a proportional increase in welfare. • And a loss of income causes a disproportional loss of welfare.

  9. Risk aversion • For the risk averse, a $20,000 increase in wealth has less affect on welfare than a $20,000 decrease in wealth. • As a result, people value ways to avoid risk. • Risk averse people will give extra value to polices that would avoid natural disasters.

  10. Valuing reduced risk of death • Three primary methods of valuing reduced risk of death: • Wage-risk studies: infer value of a life from wage and risk tradeoffs involving on-the-job risks, • Averting behavior studies: infer value of life by examining purchases that affect mortality risk, such as bicycle helmets, and • Stated preference studies: surveys that ask about WTP for reduced mortality risk.

  11. Valuing reduced risk of death • What happened to the value of foregone earnings as a measure of the value of life? • Method has been rejected. • Not based on WTP for small risk reduction.

  12. Characterizing mortality effects • Reduced mortality is measured as ‘statistical lives saved’. • Aggregation of many small risks over an exposed population. • Formula: ‘statistical lives saved’ = reduction in risk per individual * size of population.

  13. Statistical lives saved • Example: A policy reduces risk of mortality by one in 10,000 for each individual. • The population affected by the policy is 100,000. • ‘Statistical lives saved’ = (1/10,000)*100,000 = 10 persons. • 10 premature deaths would be averted by this policy.

  14. Reduced risk of death • Q: How do people value an increase in the risk of death? • A: The compensation they would accept in exchange for a small increase in the likelihood of death.

  15. Reduced risk of death • Formula: value of the risk of mortality = WTA / change in risk of death. • Example: suppose a construction worker is willing to work in an occupation that pays $1,000 more, but has a 3 in 10,000 chance of death compared with 1 in 10,000 for other occupations. • Value of mortality = $1,000 / ((3-1)/10,000) = $5 million.

  16. Reduced risk of death • $5 million is the value of a statistical life (VSL) for a construction worker. • This is how much construction workers are willing to trade for one of their lives. • Value of a life on average. • Could potentially be used in environmental benefits studies.

  17. Application: valuing reduced mortality risks to children • Uses estimates from averting behavior to measure the statistical value of life for children. • Only such study.

  18. Application: valuing reduced mortality risks to children using bicycle helmets • Infers valuation through purchase of safety products (averting behaviors). • Purchase product if value for the reduced risk is greater than the cost of the helmet. • VSL (value of statistical life): cost of helmet / change in the probability of death due to helmet purchase. • Lower bound for VSL.

  19. Application: valuing reduced mortality risks to children • Determining the annualized cost of a helmet • Assume helmet lifetime is four years. • Use an average of helmet market prices. • Ages 5-9 and 10-14: $6.51 per year. • Ages 20-59: $10.76 per year.

  20. Application: valuing reduced mortality risks to children • Determining reduced risk of mortality Risk reduction = deaths prevented / bike riding population.

  21. Application: valuing reduced mortality risks to children • VSL estimates (assume helmet worn 100% of time) • Ages 5-9: • VSL = $6.51 / 0.0000044 = $1.5 million. • Ages 10-14: • VSL = $6.51 / 0.0000061 = $1.1 million. • Ages 20-59: • VSL = $10.76 / 0.0000054 = $2.0 million.

  22. Application: valuing reduced mortality risks to children • What if helmets worn less than 100% of the time? • Reduction of risk is much lower. • But resulting VSL is higher. • Ages 5-9 • 55.3% always wear a helmet instead of 100%. • Deaths prevented = 63.06 * 0.553 = 34.87. • Reduction of risk = 0.00244*10-3. • VSL = $6.51 / 0.00000244 = $2.7 million.

  23. Application: valuing reduced mortality risks to children • VSL when helmets worn less than 100% of the time (55.3%) is $2.7 million. • Recall than VSL is $1.5 million when helmets worn 100% of the time. • Why the difference?

  24. Reduced risk of sickness • Q: How do people value a reduction in risk of sickness? • A: The sacrifice they would make to improve the chances of not being sick. • Formula: The benefit of risk reduction = WTP / change in risk of illness.

  25. Valuing reduced risk of sickness • Example: I am willing to pay $10 a year to reduce the risk of knee surgery from 5 in 1,000 to 2 in 1,000. • The benefit to me of reducing the risk of illness: $10 / ((5-2)/1,000) = $3,333. • This is the implied value of avoiding illness.

  26. Methods for valuing morbidity • Desired measure: WTP to reduce the risk of illness. • Ideally, should capture the following: • Costs of averting behavior, • Mitigating costs (cost of disease treatment), • Indirect costs (value of lost time), and • Value of discomfort, pain, suffering. • The goal is to measure the total impact of illness on individual welfare or utility.

  27. Costs of averting behavior • Actions people take to avoid the risks and consequences of the reduction of environmental quality. • Examples: • Purchase of air filters, • Boiling water, • Preventative medical care and treatment.

  28. Valuing time (digression) • Lost time due to illness: • Work time, • Leisure activities, and • Production of household goods and services (cooking, laundry, etc). • Measure for work time: wages plus benefits. • Measure for non-work time: after-tax wages.

  29. Wage-risk study • Probability of being killed by a felon: • Public: 0.3 in ten thousand (0.3*10-4). • Policeman: 1.3 in ten thousand (1.3*10-4). • Suppose police receive $700 more in income than the average worker (after adjustments).

  30. Wage-risk study • VSL = WTA risk / change in risk. • WTA risk = $700 per year. • Change in risk = (1.3-0.3)/10,000 • VSL = $700 / ((1.3-0.3)/10,000)) = $7.0 million. • On average, police are willing to trade $7 million for one of their lives.

  31. Issues with VSL • Is $7 million an accurate measure of the value of life for environmental studies? • Three issues: • 1) Accurate information: do police and other workers accurately estimate the mortality risk in their jobs? • 2) Selection bias: policemen may be more comfortable with risk, not representative of other occupations, and • 3) Involuntary nature of risk: some occupations voluntarily accept risk for more compensation; environmental damage is usually involuntary; who has the right? • Studies use regression analysis to attempt to control for these issues.

  32. Summary • Most people are risk averse. • The value of a reduction of the risk of sickness or death depends on: • willingness to pay to avoid risk, and • the reduction in risk. • Value of life or sickness can be measured by: • Wage-risk studies, • Averting behavior studies, and • Stated preference studies.

  33. Summary • Statistical lives saved = reduction in risk of death per person * number of persons. • Value of life = (WTP or WTA) / (change in risk of death. • Value of reducing risk of sickness = WTP / change in risk of sickness.

  34. Summary • Life/sickness measures should capture all of the following: • Costs of averting behavior, • Mitigating costs, • Indirect costs, and • Value of discomfort, pain, suffering

  35. Summary • VSL can be used in environmental studies if three issues are dealt with: • Do people have accurate information regarding risks? • Is there selection bias? • Is the risk involuntary?

  36. Application: Calculating the value of life Calculating the Value of Life As an economist, you have been doing a project trying to estimate the willingness-to-accept risk on the part of workers. You have gathered data on a variety of blue-collar occupations, ranging from clerical work to truck driving to coal mining. Controlling for age, gender, education, work experience and race, you have uncovered the following relationship:

  37. Application: Calculating the value of life • Graph shows roughly $400 in additional wages for each 1/10,000 reduction in mortality risk. • What is the value of a statistical life? • What three assumptions are implicit in your estimate that would affect the application of your figure to environmental damage?

  38. Application: Calculating the value of life • VSL = WTA / change in risk • = $400 / (1/10,000) • = $4,000,000. • Result can be generalized to the overall population if we assume: • Workers have accurate information about risks, • The sample of workers is representative of all workers, and • The risk accepted is voluntary. Much environmental damage is not, so this estimate would probably be low.

More Related