1.11k likes | 1.45k Views
Building Public Infrastructure in a Representative Democracy. Marco Battaglini Princeton University and CEPR Salvatore Nunnari Caltech Thomas Palfrey Caltech. Public Infrastructure. New dynamic approach to the political economy of public investment
E N D
Building Public Infrastructure in a Representative Democracy Marco Battaglini Princeton University and CEPR Salvatore Nunnari Caltech Thomas Palfrey Caltech Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Public Infrastructure • New dynamic approach to the political economy of public investment • Many public goods are durable and cannot be produced overnight. Call this Public Infrastructure • Examples: • Transportation networks • Defense infrastructure • Three key features of public infrastructure: • Public good • Durability – current investment has lasting value • Dynamics – takes time to build Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Government and Public Infrastructure • A major function of governments is the development and maintenance of lasting public goods. • How do political institutions affect provision? • Federalist systems: Decentralized • Provinces, States, Counties, etc. • Centralized/Representative: Legislatures and Parliaments Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Theoretical Approach • Simple infinite horizon model of building public infrastructure. Similar to capital accumulation models • Characterize the planner’s (optimal) solution as benchmark • Compare Institutions for making these decisions • Two models • Centralized (Representative Legislature): • Legislative bargaining model • Decentralized (Autarky) • Simultaneous independent decision making at district level Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Empirical Approach • Laboratory Experiments • Control the driving parameters (“environment”) of model • Preferences, Technology, Endowments • Mechanism: Rules of the game • Incentivize behavior with money • Theory gives us predictions • Equilibrium behavior and Time paths of investment • Differences across mechanisms and environments • Experiments give us data • Compare theory and data Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Model • n districts, i=1,…,n each of equal size • Infinite horizon. Discrete time • Two goods • Private good x • Public good g (durable). Initial level g0 • Public policy in period t:zt=(xt,gt) where xt=(xt1,…,xtn) • Each district endowment in each period ωti=W/n • Societal endowment W • Endowment can be consumed (xt ) or invested (It) • Public good technology. Depreciation rate d Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Model Feasibility Budget balance Can rewrite Budget balance as: Preferences u´´ () < 0 u´() > 0 u´(0) = ∞ u´(∞) = 0 Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Planner’s Problem (optimum) Denote: value function vp(.) aggregate consumption X=Σxi Notice y≥0 constraint not binding because of Inada conditions Hence rewrite optimization problem as: Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Optimal Policy • Denote optimal policy by y^(g). Optimal steady state yp* • Three phases: • Rapid growth It = W • Maintenance of steady state 0 < It < W • Decline It≤ 0 • Depends on whether nonnegativity constraint on consumption is binding Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Optimal Path • Case 1: Constraint binding ¶ Rapid growth • I= W • yt = W + (1-d)gt-1 • Case 2: Constraint not binding. Steady state: y* = W + (1-d)gt-1 • Solves: nu´(y*) + v´(y*) = 1 • Corresponds to two phases • Maintenance of steady state 0 < It < W • Decline It≤ 0 Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Optimal Path • Switch from growth to maintenance phase at gp Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Optimal Path Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Optimal Path Summary of optimal policy: Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Planner’s solution 1 y(g) y*p 1-d W gp gp/(1-d) g Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Planner’s solution 2 y(g) y*p W gp gp/(1-d) g Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Optimal Path: Example u(y) = yα/ α Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Legislative Mechanism Legislature decides policy in each period • Non-negative transfers, x1,…,xn • Level of public good y= (1-d)g + W – Σxi • Random recognition rule • Proposer offers proposal (x,y) • Committee votes using qualified majority rule (q) • If proposal fails, then y = 0, xi = ωi = W/n for all i Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Legislative Mechanism Proposer’s Maximization Problem: Note: (1) Proposal is (x,s,y) (2) s is the private allocation offered to each of the (q-1) other members of the coalition. (3) x is the private allocation to the proposer (4) First constraint is IC: Other members of the coalition are willing to vote for the proposal. (5) v() is the value function for continuing next period at state y. Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Legislative Mechanism Proposer’s Maximization Problem: Several cases, depending on state, g=yt-1, and on whether IC is binding. Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
In the other case, we have W-y(g)+(1-d)g=0, i.e., x(g)=0. This occurs when g < g1(y1*) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
IC Binding s > 0 CASE Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
IC Binding s = 0 CASE Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
LEGISLATIVE MECHANISM INVESTMENT FUNCTION Note: Investment function is not monotonically decreasing! Investment is increasing in third region g2 < g < g3 Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Legislative Mechanism 1 y*2 y*1 1 45o g1 g2 g3 y*2/(1-d) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Legislative Mechanism 1 q’>q y*2 y*1 1 g1 g2 g3 y*2/(1-d) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Legislative Mechanism 2 y*2 y*1 1 45o g1 g2 g3 y*2/(1-d) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Legislative Mechanism 3 y*2 y*1 1 45o g1 g2 g3 y*2/(1-d) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
LEGISLATIVE MECHANISM VALUE FUNCTION Note: Value function is monotonically increasing! Investment is increasing in third region g2 < g < g3 Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
LEGISLATIVE MECHANISM VALUE FUNCTION Relationship between v and (y1*,y2*) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Illustration of Legislative Bargaining Equilibrium u=2y1/2 n=3 q=2 W=15 δ=.75 d=0 Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
COMPUTING THE EQUILIBRIUM Exploit the relationship between v and (y1*,y2*) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Autarky Mechanism In each period, each district simultaneously decides it’s own policy for how to divide ωi = W/n between private consumption and public good investment. District can disinvest up to 1/n share of g Symmetric Markov perfect equilibrium Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Autarky Mechanism District’s Maximization Problem: A symmetric equilibrium is a district-consumption function x(g) For each g, a district chooses the district-optimal feasible xi taking as given that other districts’ current decision is given by x(g), and assuming that all districts’ future decisions in the future are given by x(g) Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Autarky Mechanism Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Autarky Mechanism Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
The Autarky Mechanism Example with power utility function u = Byα/α: [Typo: Exponent Should be 1/(1-α)] In planner’s solution, the denominator equals 1-(1-d)δ Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Autarky Mechanism y*v 1-d 1 gV Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Summary of theory and possible extensions • New Approach to the Political Economy of Public Investment. • Applies equally as a model of capital accumulation • Centralized representative system much better than decentralized • Still significant inefficiencies with majority rule • Higher q leads to greater efficiency theoretically • Why not q=n? • Model can be extended to other political institutions • Elections • Regional aggregation (subnational) • Different legislative institutions (parties, etc.) • Model can be extended to allow for more complex economic institutions • Debt and taxation, Multiple projects, Heterogeneity Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Experimental Design Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Experimental Design Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Experiment Implementation • Discount factor implemented by random stopping rule. (pr{continue}=.75) • Game durations from 1 period to 13 periods in our data • Multiple committees simultaneously processed (5x3 and 3x4) • Payoffs rescaled to allow fractional decisions • Caltech subjects. Experiments conducted at SSEL • Multistage game software package • 10 matches in each session • Subjects paid the sum of earnings in all periods of all matches • Total earnings ranged from $20 to $50 • Sessions lasted between 1 and 2 hours Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Sample Screens:Legislative Mechanism Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow
Sample Screens:Autarky Mechanism Rationality, Behaviour and Experiments Moscow