1 / 30

Bail-In Rules and the Pricing of Italian Bank Bonds Danilo V. Mascia

Bail-In Rules and the Pricing of Italian Bank Bonds Danilo V. Mascia. co-authored with Emanuela Giacomini Fabrizio Crespi. Introduction.

kmachado
Download Presentation

Bail-In Rules and the Pricing of Italian Bank Bonds Danilo V. Mascia

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Bail-In Rules and the Pricing of Italian Bank BondsDanilo V. Mascia co-authored with Emanuela Giacomini Fabrizio Crespi

  2. Introduction • Since the onset of the Global Financial Crisis a decade ago, many European Governments were forced to intervene through capital injections and purchase of toxic assets in order to support their troubled banks (Ammann et al., 2017) and, consequently, avoid financial contagion within closely interconnected banking systems (Deutsche Bank, 2014). • Bank resolutions were costly during the 2008-2012 period, with public interventions amounting to roughly 600 billion euros (excluding guarantee schemes), that is 4.6% of the European GDP in 2012 (Benczur et al., 2017). • Because taxpayers’ money was used to manage the crisis of (mostly private) banks, public bailouts resulted unsustainable from both a financial and a political perspective.

  3. Why introducing the BRRD? • Motivated by the need to reduce the costs of bank resolutions, especially those borne by taxpayers, and in order to improve market discipline, the Parliament and the Council of the European Union approved in 2014 the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD). • Effective since January 2016, the new regulatory framework for recovery and resolution of banks gives supervisors a set of instruments to intervene at an early stage to prevent situations of bank distress – thus to ensure the business continuity and to reduce the impact on the functioning of the financial system.

  4. What does the BRRD imply? • The Directive requires that, in case of irreversible disruption of a bank, in order to restore its viability shareholders should bear losses first and then creditors, in a predefined hierarchy. • This could potentially lead creditors to see their investment written off or converted into equity (among others, Chennells and Wingfield, 2015).

  5. Why do we care? • The entry into force of the BRRD Directive can have an impact on the bank funding costs because the bail-in rules transfer risk from taxpayers to unsecured bondholders. • Hence, we expect holders of bail-inable instruments to ask for a higher premium on bank bonds at origination – compared to non-bail-inable bonds – as they consider the implementation of the BRRD a plausible threat for their savings. • The introduction of the BRRD might hit the banks with a different intensity depending on their intrinsic characteristics. • We believe that larger banks and riskier institutions will be the ones who will struggle the most from the introduction of the new rules – as they should not benefit from any implicit public guarantee anymore.

  6. What have researchers done so far? • The existing literature mainly focuses on the effect of the new regulatory framework on bank specific risk and financial stability. • For instance, Schäfer et al. (2016) analyze the reactions of CDS spreads and share prices related to European banks after the announcement of some bail-in actions. • Mikosek (2016) observes that the ratio of the average bank CDS spreads over sovereign CDS increases substantially, showing a sharp misalignment between sovereign and bank risk perceptions. • More recently, Giuliana (2018) – focusing on the secondary market – finds that bail-in events amplified the difference in daily yield between bail-inable (non-secured) and non-bail-inable (secured) bonds. These findings support the notion that the authorities’ efforts to introduce the bail-in regime increased the bail-in expectations in the secondary market.

  7. What we do…

  8. What we do… • We analyse whether the introduction of the bail-in tool in January 2016 affected the pricing of Italian bank bonds. • We carry out our study by relying on a unique hand-collect dataset of 1,798 fixed-rate bonds issued by Italian banks during the period 2013–2016.

  9. Why focusing on Italy…

  10. Why focusing on Italy… • Italian banks are quite dependent on bonds as a form of funding compared to banks in other European countries (Coletta and Santioni, 2016). • The portion of bank bonds in Italian retail investor’s portfolios is rather greater than the average of developed countries (Coletta and Santioni, 2016; Grasso et al., 2010). • Italian banks mostly place their bonds directly to their customers – who lack adequate financial literacy (Gentile and Siciliano, 2009) –, with an obvious conflict of interest. • In November 2015 (a few weeks before the official implementation of the BRRD), the Italian Government published the Law 180/2015 that aimed to apply a burden sharing to four small regionally chartered banks. • Although those four regionally chartered banks accounted for less than 2% of the Italian banking market, the decision regarding their quasi bail-in became the hot topic in the news for a while, which led Italians realize their savings and investments were at risk. • Hence, this event represents a unique opportunity to test whether such cases of default could have improved investors’ awareness about the negative consequences of futures bail-ins, possibly leading them to be more careful about their investment decisions.

  11. What we find…

  12. What we find… • We first document an increase of the average bond spread in 2016 with the adoption of the BRRD. Precisely, the average spread followed an interesting path during the observed period, passing from 0.56% in the pre bail-in phase (2013-2015) to 0.70% for the bonds issued after 2015. • We also find that banks characterized by lower ratings, profitability, capitalization, and higher liquidity were forced to pay higher spreads to place their bonds. • Our results suggest that the implementation of the quasi bail-in just some weeks before the effective entry into force of the BRRD contributed to lead retail investors demanding a higher premium for their investment in bail-inable bonds. • Notably, we observe that large banks were able to pay a lower spread until 2015. In contrast, since 2016 large banks seem to face a negative effect that translates into an increase in the cost of funding. Eventually, the implementation of the new Directive might have mitigated the too-big-too-fail effect, which is consistent with the findings of, among others, Zaghini (2014).

  13. Data and methodology…

  14. Dataset construction • We create a unique dataset of 1,798 bonds offered to retail investors by a sample of Italian banks during the period January 2013 – December 2016. • Data concerning the characteristics of the bonds were hand-collected from the final terms of each issuance. Notably, following Sironi (2003), we collect: • the yield to maturity at the issuing date, • the size of the issuance, • the maturity, and • the listing venue, if any. • We only include: • bonds denominated in euro, • with no optional component (e.g., callable option), • and in the fixed interest category (fixed coupon or zero coupon) – provided that non-structured bonds are the most common type of bond in Italian household portfolios (Coletta and Santioni, 2016).

  15. Dataset construction • Our analysis is restricted to 28 banks that issued bonds both before and after the introduction of the BRRD – in order to avoid potential issues related to sample selection that can bias our main results. • The majority of bonds in our dataset (about 81%) are not listed in a regulated stock exchange or MTF. • Since our goal is to study the impact that the adoption of the BRRD has generated on the cost of funding borne by banks when issuing bonds, we refer exclusively to the returns offered in the primary market – following the approach used, among others, by Morgan and Stiroh (2001) and Sironi (2003).

  16. Summary statistics • Entire period: • Pre and post 2016:

  17. Empirical setting • The main model specification is the following: • The second model adds interactions to investigate if significant differences in investors’ reaction, due to the bank characteristics, emerge: • Bond Var: maturity, size, listed, step-up • Bank Var: rating, size, TBTF, Tier1 ratio, ROA, liquid assets, NPL

  18. Results…

  19. Results 1/2

  20. Results 2/2

  21. Robustness…

  22. Anticipation effect – November 2015

  23. Anticipation effect – April 2014

  24. Excluding Banca Carige, Veneto Banca, and BancApulia

  25. Excluding the banks that did not issue covered bonds

  26. Excluding the two major issuers (UBI and Cariparma)

  27. Utilizing alternative proxies of the bank characteristics

  28. Conclusions…

  29. Conclusions • Overall, we find that Italian banks experience, on average, a higher bond funding cost upon the introduction of the new regulatory framework. • Additional analyses also highlight that such an effect significantly emerged right after the decision of the Italian Resolution Authority to implement a burden sharing to 4 small banks in November 2015. • This confirms the existence of a bail-in effect on the cost of funding borne by the banks through the issuance of bonds, which can be on average quantified as +14 basis points in comparison to the previous period. • Our results offer interesting policy implications because, as prescribed by the new legislation, Authorities should also count on market discipline to improve their prudential supervision. Higher risk sensitivity, indeed, is especially needed in countries like Italy where, historically, market discipline has not been working properly.

  30. Thank you! Danilo.Mascia@nottingham.ac.uk

More Related