1 / 33

Chapter 7 Production and Costs: Many Variable Inputs

Chapter 7 Production and Costs: Many Variable Inputs. Isoquants and Input Substitution. An isoquant is a curve composed of all bundles that produce some fixed quantity of output. An example: y =(1200z 1 z 2 ) 1/2 Setting y =120 and simplifying gives 12= z 1 z 2 (see Figure 7.1).

jmcclean
Download Presentation

Chapter 7 Production and Costs: Many Variable Inputs

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 7Production and Costs: Many Variable Inputs

  2. Isoquants and Input Substitution • An isoquant is a curve composed of all bundles that produce some fixed quantity of output. • An example: y=(1200z1z2)1/2 • Setting y =120 and simplifying gives 12=z1z2 • (see Figure 7.1).

  3. Figure 7.1 Isoquants for courier services

  4. Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS) • The marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) measures the rate at which one input can be substituted for the other, with output remaining constant. • The MRTS is the absolute value of the slope of the isoquant.

  5. Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements • Inputs are perfect substitutes when one output can always be substituted for the other on fixed terms and the MRTS is constant. • With perfect complements, substitution is impossible and the MRTS cannot be defined for the bundle at the kink in the isoquant.

  6. Figure 7.2 Some illustrative isoquants

  7. Diminishing Rate of Technical Substitution • Most cases fall between perfect substitutes and perfect complements. In these cases, one input can be substituted for the other but the MRTS is not constant. • In such cases, it becomes increasingly difficult to substitute one input for the other. • This means the MRTS diminishes moving from left to right along the isoquant.

  8. Figure 7.3 The marginal rate of technical substitution, MRTS

  9. MRTS as a Ratio of Marginal Products • When the quantity of input 1 is decreased by Δz1, the change in y is (approx) the marginal product of the input times the change in the quantity of input 1. • Therefore: Δy=MP1Δyz1 • Similarly: Δy=MP2Δyz2

  10. MRTS as a Ratio of Marginal Products • When z1 is very small, MRTS can be approximated by Δz2/Δz1 • Solving for z1 & z2 and substituting from above yields MRTS = (Δy/MP2)(Δy/MP1) • Reducing gives MRTS = MP1/MP2 • Therefore MRTS is equal to the marginal product of input 1 divided by the marginal product of input 2.

  11. Returns to Scale • Increasing returns to scale occurs when increasing all inputs by X% increases output by more than X%. • Constant returns to scale occurs when an increase in all inputs of X% increases output by X%. • Decreasing returns to scale occurs when an increasing all inputs by X% increases output by less than X%.

  12. Figure 7.4 Constant returns to scale

  13. The Cost Minimization Problem: A Perspective • The cost function shows the minimum cost of producing any level of output in the long-run. • The long-run cost minimizing problem is: minimize w1z1+w2+z2 choosing z1 and z2 subject to constraint y=F(z1, z2)

  14. Conditional Input Demand Functions • The solution to the cost minimization problem gives the values of the endogenous variables (z1* & z2*) as a function of the exogenous variables (y, w1 and w2). • Since z1* & z2* are dependent upon the level of ychosen, the input demand functions are described as conditional demand functions.

  15. The Long-run Cost Function • Once we know the input demand functions, the long-run cost function is the sum of the input quantities and their respective prices. TC(y,w1,w2) = w1z1* +w2z2*

  16. Solving Cost Minimization Problems • The isocost line shows all bundles of inputs that cost the same. It can be expressed as: c= w1z1+w2z2. • The absolute value of the slope of the isocost line is w1/w2. • This slope says that w1/w2of input 2 must be given up to get an additional unit of input 1. • The slope is the opportunity cost of input 1 in terms of input 2.

  17. Figure 7.5 The cost-minimizing bundle

  18. Principles of Cost Minimization • The cost minimizing input bundle is on the isoquant: y Ξ F(z1* +z2*). • The MRTS is equal to w1/w2 at the cost minimizing bundle: MRTS(z1*z2*) Ξ w1/w2 The second principle can be generalized by stating the marginal product per dollar must be identical for all inputs.

  19. Comparative Statics for Input Prices • If all input prices change by the same factor of proportionality (a): • The cost of minimizing the input bundle for y units of output does not change. • The minimum cost of producing y units of output changes by the factor of proportionality (a).

  20. Figure 7.7 Costs and input prices

  21. From Figure 7.7 • If the cost-minimizing quantity of both inputs (i and j) is positive, and there is diminishing MRTS, if piincreases and pj does not, the cost minimizing quantity of i increases and j decreases. • If the price of an input increases and the quantity demanded of that input is positive, the minimum cost of producing any level of output rises.

  22. Comparative Statics: Level of Output • The expansion path connects the cost minimizing bundles that are generated as output increases. • A normal input is one where the quantity demanded increases when output rises. • An inferior input is one where the quantity demanded decreases when output rises.

  23. Figure 7.8 The output expansion path

  24. Homothetic Production Functions • A homothetic production function is a type of function where the expansion path is a ray through the origin. • For these types of functions the MRTS is constant along any ray from the origin.

  25. Long-run Costs and Output • Long-run average costs (LAC) is equal to the total cost of output (TC) divided by the quantity of output (y): LAC(y)=TC(y)/y • As output rises, LAC is constant, decreasing, or increasing as there are constant, increasing, or decreasing returns to scale.

  26. Figure 7.9 Costs and returns to scale

  27. Figure 7.10 More on costs and returns to scale

  28. Long-run Marginal Cost • Long-run marginal cost (LMC) is the rate at which costs increase as output increases (the slope of TC). • When LMC lies below LAC, LAC is decreasing, when LMC exceeds LAC, LAC is rising, LMC intersects LAC at the LAC minimum.

  29. Figure 7.11 Deriving LAC and LMC from TC

  30. Figure 7.12 Comparing TC and STC

  31. Figure 7.13 Relationships between long-run and short-run cost functions

  32. Figure 7.14 A cost-based theory of market structure

  33. From Figure 7.14 • U-shaped cost curves reflect initial increasing and subsequent decreasing returns to scale. • If LAC attains its minimum at a relatively large level of output, we expect to see a monopoly or oligopoly. • If LAC attains its minimum at a relatively small level of output, we expect to see a competitive market.

More Related