1 / 23

Workshop OEET , Torino, March 12-13/2015

Structural Change, Globalization and Economic Growth in China and India Vittorio Valli and Donatella Saccone (University of Turin). Workshop OEET , Torino, March 12-13/2015.

jmalinda
Download Presentation

Workshop OEET , Torino, March 12-13/2015

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Structural Change, Globalization and Economic Growth in China and IndiaVittorio Valli and Donatella Saccone (University of Turin) Workshop OEET, Torino, March 12-13/2015

  2. Aim of the paper: to analyze, in a comparative perspective, the relation between structural change, the process of globalization and economic growth in two great emerging economies, China and India, in their period of rapid development. • Antecedents for structural change: • Akamatsu (1935, 1962) in a original way, the "wild-geese-flying approach" then generalized by Kiyoshi Kojima (2000) and Ozawa (2001) and (2010). • The structural view was also independently furthered in a different way by other great authors such as Colin Clark (1940), who inaugurated the three-sectors approach, Simon Kuznets (1957) and Alexander Gerschenkron (1962). • Between the 1960s and the late 1980s the main contributions are due to Chenery (1960), Chenery and Taylor (1968 ), Taylor (1969), Keesinkg and Sherk (1971), Chenery and Syrquin (1975), Chenery et al. (1979), Kader (1985), Chenery, Robinson and Syrquin (1986), Syrquin (1988), Chenery and Syrquin (1989). Introduction -1

  3. Recent contributions have mainly focused on cross-country analyses, more disaggregated approaches and country studies. • For example, Haraguchi and Rezonja (UNIDO) (2010), De Vries, et al. (2012), McMillan and Rodrik. (2011), Lin (2011), Lin and Rosenblutt (2012) have carried out important cross-country analyses; Li, Menginstae et al. (2011) have focused on China and India; Kochhar et al. (2006) on India; Wang et al. (2007) on China. • However, most of the cross-country studies have jointly studied market or mixed economies, often overlooking the particular structural features of Communist central planned economies like China up to 1978 as well as of heavily regulated mixed economies like India up to 1992. These features have heavily influenced the period of transition and rapid growth in the two great Asian economies. Countries in profound transition between different systemic mechanisms of regulation and control in the economy may have very different structural transformations with respect to countries that in the same period have fully maintained their systemic characteristics. Introduction -2

  4. Few contributions have tried to analyze the relations between structural change, globalization and economic growth. • The initial conditions, the pace of economic growth, the timing and the way in which a country has entered the globalization process are fundamental in order to understand the different economic structures of China and India and their change over time. Introduction -3

  5. Initial structural conditions -1

  6. As table 1 shows: • In 1978, the percentage share of agriculture in total employment was about the same in the two countries, while the percentage in value added was much higher in India. • Although in 1978 India had a level of per capita GDP in PPPs somewhat higher than China, the share of industry was already higher in China than in India, in terms both of value added and employment, while the share of services was much lower in China than in India. • This is largely a consequence of a systemic difference, namely the fact that China was a Communist centrally planned economy, where services were usually overlooked and heavy industry was strongly privileged over light industry, services and agriculture. • Moreover, China’s industry was essentially constituted by large state companies with an average productivity higher than that of India’s industry, sharply divided between a relatively small number of large state or private companies and many firms of the informal economy exhibiting a very low productivity. However, in agriculture productivity was higher in India than in China. Initial structural conditions -2

  7. Economic development and structural change: an overview -1

  8. Economic development and structural change: an overview -2

  9. As tables 2 and 3 show: • China’s rapid economic growth began in 1978 and further accelerated since 1992, with the brisk insertion in the globalization process, while India accelerated its growth later on, in the second half of the 1980s and in particular since 1992, thereafter considerably opening up its economy. • China’s per capita GDP surpassed India’s at the beginning of the 1980s, while as to the level of productivity China surpassed India only in the 1990s. • Since 1978, China’s capital accumulation was much greater than India’s. • Total employment rose in the two countries more or less at the same rate of growth in the period 1978-1992, but rose much more in India than in China in the second period 1992-2012, while tha rate of activity and of employment of the population remained higher in China. Economic development and structural change: an overview -3

  10. Economic development and structural change: an overview -4

  11. If we concentrate the analysis on the structural changes occurred in the two countries in the period covered by our disaggregated data set (1987-2009), we can see (table 4) that China reduced the percentage of agriculture both in employment and in valued added, and increased the absolute and relative size of its industrial sector much more than India. The exceptionally rapid rise in investment, value added and productivity in China has mainly regarded the industrial sector, while agriculture and services have contributed less. However, the share of services in employment constantly grew also in China surpassing in the 1990s the share of industry. • Indeed, if compared to India (but also to other developing and emerging economies), China’s process of industrialization has been much more rapid and extensive, while the service sector, starting from a very low level, has grown substantially. However, it has remained less extensive than in India. India has reached, and then surpassed, the average percentage level of the tertiary sector of several other developing and emerging countries, improving in particular the specialization in the production and export of software and other ICT services. Economic development and structural change: an overview -5

  12. Some of the main determinants of the different patterns of development in the two countries may be so summarized: • A) In 1978 China had already a larger industrial base than India, although China had then a lower per capita GDP. • B) Since 1978 China has introduced radical economic reforms that have strongly favored industrialization much earlier than India (about 14-15 years in advance). • C) China’s rate of saving and investment has been much larger than in India, and investment went mainly to manufacturing industry, constructions and a part of the services sector. • D) China favored industrialization more than India maintaining relatively low prices for agricultural goods and for some basic inputs provided by state corporations. • E) China had an extensive use of the fordist- toyotist model of growth, while India limited it almost exclusively to the formal sector, which employs only about one tenth of the total labor force. (Valli and Saccone (2009). • F) China opened its economy to external trade and foreign investment earlier and much more extensively than India, as we will see in next paragraph. • G) In the 1978-2012 period in China there was a vast increase in income and wealth inequalities, while absolute poverty diminished. In India the rise in inequalities was less severe, but there remained a large level of absolute and relative poverty. • H) In China the extraordinarily rapid process of industrialization and urbanization and the absence of adequate environmental policies led to a great rise of pollution. In India the rise in pollution was substantial, but lower than in China. Economic development and structural change: an overview -6

  13. The globalization process

  14. The timing and the particular way in which China and India structurally transformed their economy and entered into the globalization process had important consequences on various social problems: • A) Increase in economic inequalities both between families and regions: very rapid and severe in China, less severe, but substantial in India. Rise also of inequalities in education. Persistence of large, though decreasing, illiteracy in India. • B) poverty: absolute poverty decreased more in China than in India, but in China peasants in poor rural areas and internal illegal immigrants have very bad working conditions and poor social welfare. In India people living in poor rural areas or in city slums and working in the informal sectors have often even worse living conditions. • C) pollution: rapidly increasing in China; increasing at a lower rate in India. • D) several socio-political problems associated to the high level of corruption, the deficit of democracy in the Chinese political system and the great ethnic, religious, and caste divisions in India. Structural change, globalization and social problems

  15. A more disaggregated analysis is based on decomposing the changes in aggregate labor productivity for China and India. Our database consists in time series data from 1987 to 2009 on the value added at 1995 constant price, employment and productivity at a detailed 33 sector level for China and 31 for India. • In order to construct our database and obtain consistent time series from 1987 to 2009, we matched two different sources of data both elaborated as projects of the Groningen Growth and Development Centre (GGDC). • A) the BRICs sector database (De Vries et al., 2012) for the years 1987-2008 and B) WIOD (World Input Output database (Timmer, 2012) for the period 1995-2009. • So, we obtained a new database for the period 1987-2009, with 33 sectors for China and 31 sectors for India. A disaggregated analysis on labor productivity - 1

  16. The database is then used to analyze the changes in the aggregate productivity level. Indeed, the latter can originate from both changes in productivity within each sector and the movement of labor across sectors presenting different levels of productivity. • To take into account these two different effects, the first called ‘within effect’ and the second called ‘reallocation effect’, we use the methodology originally proposed by Fabricant (1942) and adopted in recent studies on structural change (see de Vries et al., 2012; McMillan and Rodrik, 2011). • At first, we just consider the three main economic sectors, i.e. agriculture, industry and services. The change in the aggregate productivity level can be written as a sum of the two effects: • The first addend represents the ‘within effect’ and the second addend the ‘reallocation effect’. The ‘reallocation effect’ can be also considered as a residual given by the difference between the aggregate productivity change and the ‘within effect’ (de Vries et al., 2012), and it can be seen as an index of structural change. • Secondly, following another formula by De Vries et al. (2012) we carried out the decomposition of the aggregate productivity changes by considering both the changes across the three main economic sectors I (reallocation effect 2) and the changes across the subsectors j within each of the three sector I(reallocation effect 1). A disaggregated analysis on labor productivity - 2

  17. Productivity growth decomposition -1 China

  18. Given the predominant contribution of the within effect to the total productivity growth, it is useful to individuate which sectors and subsectors have been more dynamic in terms of productivity over the analyzed period. • From 1987 to 2009, productivity grew by the 481% in the whole economy, while in each sector it increased by the 170% in agriculture, the 611% in industry and the 258% in services. It is evident that the major productivity gains occurred in industry. In particular, some industrial subsectors presented an outstanding performance of productivity: transport equipment (+ 1630%), other non-metallic mineral (+ 1618%), manufacturing not elsewhere classified and recycling (+ 1377%), machinery not elsewhere classified (+ 1162%), basic metals (+ 1029%), electrical and optical equipment (+ 1001%), followed by mining and quarrying (+814% ), wood and cork (+ 722%), chemicals and chemical products (+ 624%), food , beverages and tobacco (+ 598%), rubber and plastics (+ 569%), and leather and footwear (+ 526%). • In the remaining industrial subsectors (textiles; pulp, paper, printing and publishing; coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel; electricity, gas and water supply; construction) productivity increased but at a slower pace than total productivity. • The service sector was, on the contrary, more polarized between subsectors with remarkable productivity gains and subsectors with a performance below or in line with the total productivity growth. Among the first: post and telecommunications (+ 2660%), water transport (+ 2195%), renting of machinery and equipment, and other business activities (+ 1071%), health and social work (+ 801%), and public administration, defence and compulsory social security (781%). Productivity growth de-composition: China - 2

  19. Productivity growth de-composition India- 1

  20. If compared to the Chinese path of structural change, it can be noticed that India followed a more balanced, but slower and less definite path. • In China, the increase in the productivity within sectors and subsectors, in particular in industry, was the driving force of total productivity growth. After an initial slowdown in the total productivity growth, it constantly increased over the analyzed period, with a moderate deceleration from 1997 to 2002 caused by a too pronounced decrease in the employment share in industry rather than a reduction of productivity growth. • On the contrary, in India the increases in total productivity were lower and not constant, with important effects deriving from smaller productivity gains within sectors and subsectors, misallocation of labor across subsectors and a still high share of workers employed in agriculture (54% in 2009). Only in recent years, and in particular from 2005, it seems that in India the rates of productivity growth reached levels similar to the Chinese performance. Among many differences between the two countries, we have to take into particular account two of these. First, the economic reforms in China began around 15 years before than in India and, then, it is possible that a clearer path of structural change will occur in India in the next years. Second, India is characterized by a huge presence of the informal sector, that could have decelerated the possibility of high productivity gains and hindered a stable path of structural change. Productivity growth de-composition India compared with China

  21. We further investigated the relation of structural change with both economic growth and globalization by adopting VAR models. • Three main results emerged from our analysis. • First of all, there exist important feedbacks between structural change and economic growth over time. Present values of the index of structural change and per-capita GDP growth are related to past values of each other. • Second, when the reallocation of labor is large, it may positively impact on the future rates of economic growth, At the same time, however, it seems that a too rapid economic growth may have hindered a suitable reallocation of labor. New policies should be designed to favor the voluntary labor movement across sectors and areas, to reduce the wage-productivity differentials and to integrate the informal sector in formal markets in India, in order to foster structural change and further enhance economic growth. • Third, if a too unbalanced economic growth has limited the extent of structural change, globalization has promoted it. High level of export, import and FDI not only has been related to higher rates of economic growth, but also to a better reallocation of resources across sectors, modifying the comparative advantage and reorganizing production. An econometric exercise

  22. China. VAR estimation.Granger and Var stability condition respected

  23. India. VAR estimation. Granger and Var stability condition respected

More Related