1 / 61

In the simple market equilibrium model, there can be no involuntary unemployment.

This article explores the causes and effects of unemployment, with a focus on the US and Europe. It discusses the impact of unemployment on individuals and society, as well as factors such as gender, age, and education that affect unemployment rates. The article also analyzes the inflow and duration of unemployment.

Download Presentation

In the simple market equilibrium model, there can be no involuntary unemployment.

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. UnemploymentEfficiencywagesBorjas, 11.5 and ch. 12 + article by Yellen (12.1, just read through, you do not haveto ”temporarylay-offs”, pp 521-524, 12.6, 12.7, 12.9) • In the simple market equilibrium model, there can be no involuntary unemployment. • One of the most difficult tasks for economists has been (and is) to explain how unemployment can exist.

  2. Unemploymentdoesexist: • The Great Depression – one quarter to a third of all workers unemployed in the industrialised countries. • In Sweden in 1933, 22% of trade-union members were unemployed. • After 1933, unemployment fell almost steadily and in the 1950s stabilised at about 2% and remained near that level until the early 1980s. It did not reach 4 % before the depression of the 1990s.

  3. In other European countries unemployment was also low in the 1950s and 1960s but increased sharply after the ”oil-shock” of the early 1970s. • UE in ”OECD-Europe” in 1980 was 6% (2% in Sweden) • During the 1990s depression Swedish unemployment rates were only a little below the European average. But when they started to fall (1998) they fell more rapidly in Sweden.

  4. Unemployment as a social and economic issue. • Unemployment has negative effects on the health and well-beingof the unemployed and theirfamilies. It canleadto social exclusion, especially for the long-term unemployed. • There is an opportunitycosttosocietyofwhat the unemployedcouldhaveproduced. • A long period ofunemploymentleadsto loss ofskills and experience. Thismeanslowerfutureearnings for the individual and lowerproductivity for the economy. • Unemploymentleadstoincreaseddifferences in living standards and to social conflicts and tension, particularlyifsomegroupsaremoreaffectedthanothers. • Unemploymentinsurance and social securityto the unemployedhaveto be paid by the public sector.

  5. The US and Europe • In1960s unemployment was twice as high in the US as in most European countries and remained higher until the late 1970s. • Since the early 1980s, US unemployment rates have decreased (with one minor upturn) while European mostly have not. • During the 1990s recession, EU unemployment rates soared, while the US decreased.

  6. Unemployment rates in Sweden, the EU15 and the USSource: Laborsta (ILO)

  7. Unemployment 1998-2009 Age 15-74

  8. A fewmorecountries(compareBorjas fig. 12-19)

  9. Is the ILO-unemployment rate the onlymeasure of ”success”? • In Sweden (2006) onecouldtakeintoaccount : • UE (old definition) was 5.4% • Students wantingtowork 2 %. • Other latent unemployment 2 %. • Persons in labour market programs. • Earlyretirement ”for labour market reasons”. • Involuntary part-time (partial unemployment)

  10. Unemployed and in labour market programs in % of LF1990-2002 (Source: Labour Market Board, AMS) UE + in LMP = total

  11. In the US one could take into account (but not simply add): • Discouraged job-seekers (about 1% of LF) • Involuntary part-time (Borjas fig. 12-5) • Prison population (2.3 m in 2006, eq. to 1.5 % of the labour force). • Working poor.

  12. Having said this:Who is more/less likely to be unemployed? • 1. Gender • Traditionally women had higher unemployment rates than men. That is not necessarily true today. • In Sweden, female UE was a little higher than the male up to 1980, then ≈ equal. In the 1990s, more men were unemployed. (Manufacturing reduced workforce more than the public sector.) • In some other countries too, like Norway & UK, there is lower UE among women. In others, there is higher. (In Spain, Italy & Greece about twice as high as that of men.)

  13. 2. Age • In most countries, UE is higher among young people. • Countries with apprentice systems tend to have more young people with jobs. • But youth unemployment figures should be interpreted with care – they depend on: • Numbers unemployed. • Participation rates of young people.

  14. Source: Laborsta

  15. 3. Education. • UE-rate in LFS 2010 (%): • Less thanupperUppersecondary Post-secondary Not known secondary 18.2 7.9 5.0 31.4 (Averagewas 8.4) .

  16. Unemployment = proportion who become unemployed * the length of time they stay unemployed. • The analysis of the unemployment rate can be divided into analysis of • The inflow into unemployment • The duration of unemployment • Note that duration is the average length of unemployment of those who become unemployed at a particular time not those who are unemployed at particular time.

  17. But of the people who are unemployed in a particular month: • Example: Assume that 5 people become unemployed each month. 4 remain unemployed one month but the 5th is unemployed for 6 months. • Average duration: • (4*1 + 6)/5 = 2

  18. Howdopeople get unemployed? • The labour market is a dynamic system (Lecture 1) Employed Outside LF Unemp-loyed

  19. US (Borjas fig. 12.3): Of the unemployed • Roughly half have lost their jobs • Roughly a third have quit a job • About one tenth each of new entrants and re-entrants to the LF. • Sweden (Björklund et. al. Arbetsmarknaden based on LFS): Inflow to unemployment 2003: • 26 % new or re-entrants • 16 % redundancies • 46 % contracted work finished* • 12 % other * Was only 29% in 1980

  20. Steadystateunemployment • Let l = the proportion of workers who lose their jobs in each period h = the proportion of the unemployed who find a job in each period LF = the labour force, E = the employed, U=the unemployed • In steady state inflow=outflow lE= hU l(LF-U) = hU lLF=(h+l)U Unemployment rate =

  21. Different types of unemployment • Frictional unemployment • Seasonal unemployment • Structural unemployment • Cyclical unemployment

  22. Frictionalunemployment • – Firms go in and out of business, workers go in and out of jobs (or in and out of the LF). Information is not perfect. Workers and firms need time to ”match up”. • Policy action: Improve information to workers about job openings, and information to employers about job-searchers.

  23. Seasonalunemployment • A substantial minority of the unemployed who get work, are re-hired by a previous employer. (Partly as an effect of legislation, LAS.) • Employers may lay workers off with the mutual understanding that they will be re-hired. • Examples: Winter/summer tourism, construction • If the workers receive unemployment benefits ”the public purse” subsidises these firms

  24. Structuralunemployment • In a changing economy chances are big that skills supplied do not match skills demanded – there are both vacancies and unemployment. • Policy action: Provide and subsidise training that improves the match between supply and demand. Decrease the cost of moving to where the jobs are.

  25. Cyclicalunemployment • Theremay be moreunemployedthanvacancies. • Accordingto the supply/demand market equilibriummodel, wagesshould fall whenthere is unemployment, until the market clears. In reality, wagesaresticky, at leastdownwards. • Governmentexpenditure, taxes and benefits and interest rates influenceaggregatedemand and thereforeunemployment. Theycan be usedcounter-cyclically.

  26. Three directions in economic theories of unemployment: • Search theories of unemployment • Inflation and unemployment • Wage theories. (Why do wages not fall to the market clearing level?).

  27. 1. Search models of unemployment • It takes time and money for workers/ employers to find good worker/job matches. • Assume • unemployed workers do not know where there is a job with a particular wage • but they do know the distribution of wage offers “out there” in the market. • For example, the worker knows that the best paying job/s he/she could get have a monthly wage of 30 000 SEK but there are also jobs paying only 15 000 – and many in between.

  28. Frequency $8 $22 $5 45 Wage $25 The chance that a wage offer will be in the tails – say above 27 000 or below 18 000 is small. If the offer the worker receives is 17 000, the probability that next offer will be better is large. If the offer is 27 000 the chances that the next will be better is small. 30 15 18 27 Wage offers in 1000 SEK

  29. In a non-sequential search, the stopping rule is to stop searching after a certain number of offers (decided in advance). Not optimal – does not take into account what the offers are. • In a sequential search, the worker’s stopping rule is to stop searching when there is an offer above a certain level – the asking wage. • If the worker receives an offer at or above the asking wage, searching stops. If the offer is less than the asking wage, he/she does another search. The expected duration of unemployment is longer, the higher the worker’s asking wage.

  30. What determines the asking wage? • The cost of continuing the search – direct costs and the opportunity cost of the rejected wage offer. The higher the offer that is rejected, the larger the MC of another search round. • The higher the wage offer, the larger the marginal benefit of accepting it. • The asking wage will be the wage at which MC = MB

  31. Determinants of the asking wage • The asking wage depends on the distribution of job offers (the probability of getting job offers at different levels.) • A higher time discount rate  lower asking wage. To continue the search involves a cost now and a gain later. • Higher unemployment insurance  higher asking wage. • A long unemployment period tends to reduce the asking wage.

  32. Factors that influence the length on unemployment in a search model: • A well functioning Employment Service (Arbetsförmedling) makes search quicker. • Lower unemployment rate • makes the chance of a new offer greater • increases the asking wage. • High unemployment insurance increases the duration of unemployment • Exits from unemployment tend to increase just before a time-limit for unemployment insurance. • The asking wage tends to decrease over time • A long unemployment period reduces the chances of job offers – depreciation of skills, stigma effect, discouragement. • Search efforts may increase or decrease with time in unemployment.

  33. Duration dependence • Thus, the probability of leaving unemployment during a certain time (week, month) can vary over a period of unemployment. This is called duration dependence. • Without duration dependence for each person, observed decreasing exit rate may be due to heterogeneity – those who have the greatest difficulty finding employment will be over-represented among long-time unemployed. Probability of Leaving unempl. Positive dur. dep. No dur. dep. Negative dur. dep. Unemployment in weeks

  34. So what is a good unemployment insurance (UI) system? • With generous UI we can expect: • Longer unemployment periods. • Higher wages after unemployment. • If employers (US) or workers/unions (Sweden) pay more towards financing the UI, more account may be taken of unemployment risks in wage-setting. • Unemployment insurance and social welfare: • Ethical reasons why unemployed people who want to work should have a “decent” standard of living. • It can be economically efficient to allow the unemployed time to search for a good match.

  35. Unemployment insurance in Sweden • Entitlement to unemployment benefit depends on the following conditions. The jobseeker must: • 1. be fit and available to work for an employer at least three hours every working day and for an average of at least 17 hours per week • 2. be prepared to accept an offer of appropriate work during the period, where no impediment has been accepted as admissible by the unemployment insurance fund • 3. be registered as a jobseeker with the Employment Service, in compliance with government regulations or those applied by one of its agencies • 4. cooperate in drawing up an individual back-to-work plan in consultation with the Employment Service • 5. actively seek but be unable to find appropriate work. • 6. fulfil the work requirement (prior to becoming unemployed, you must have worked for at least six months and at least 80 hours in every calendar month, or for at least 480 hours over six consecutive calendar months and for at least 50 hours in each of these months. )

  36. If you are a member of an unemployment insurance fund you receive: • 80 % of previous income up to a maximum of 680 SEK/day for 200 days. (For parents with children under 18 it is 450 days.) • 70 % of previous income (up to SEK 680/day) for another 100 days. • If you are not a member you receive 320 SEK/day. • The compensation is reduced for a period of time if you refuse one or two job offers. • If you refuse three, you are cut off from compensation. • If you do not fulfil the requirements you do not receive UI, only social assistance (försörjningsstöd) which is much less and requires that you do not have major assets like a house, car, bonds, equity etc). Source: Arbetslöshetskassornas samorganisation. http://www.samorg.org/so/Index.aspx?id=105

  37. In addition to the state system of UI, the labour market organisations (unions & employers) have agreed to provide support to workers who are laid off: • Help in search for new jobs • Severance (redundancy) pay • Support during unemployment “topping up” the UI. • This influences the actual effect of state decisions on UI (time limits, replacement ratios)

  38. 2. Inflation and unemployment • Is there a ”trade-off” between inflation and unemployment? • A famous study (Phillips, 1958) found a negative correlation between unemployment and inflation in Britain over a century. Infl. rate UE-rate

  39. What could be behind the Phillips curve? • When there is high unemployment: • Smaller wage increases • Low aggregate demand •  Low inflationary pressure. • When there is a high level of employment: • High aggregate demand  high level of production  increased marginal costs  price increases • With low unemployment workers have good ”outside options” and can make higher wage demands •  High inflationary pressure.

  40. In Sweden in the 1950s and early 1960s, data on inflation and unemployment fit a convex Phillips curve. • To have both low unemployment and low inflation, the Phillips curve has to be ”pushed” inwards. • This was the idea behind Swedish economic and labour market policy in the post-war • According to labour economists Gösta Rehn och Rudolf Meidner it could be done with a combination of: • Restrictive fiscal policies • Solidaristic wage policy (uniting modernisation of the economy and egalitarianism) • Targeted measures to create jobs and active labour market policies

  41. Stagflation – no more Phillips curve? • From late 60s both inflation and unemployment increased. • After 1973 many countries experienced stagflation – high UE AND high inflation. • In Sweden in the 1980s UE and inflation moved in opposite directions between years but the ”curve” was farther from the origin. • Either there was no Phillips-curve, or it had shifted outwards. (Compare Borjas fig. 12-17 for the US.) • Stagflation increased the influence of neo-liberal economists like Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps.

  42. NAIRU • They claimed that in the short run there might be a negatively sloped Phillips curve but in the long run the Phillips curve was VERTICAL. There was no trade-off between unemployment and inflation. • Only one level of unemployment was compatible with a stable rate of inflation - the NAIRU – Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment. • Unemployment below NAIRU  ACCELERATING inflation. • Why? People learn to expect inflation and adjust to that. They include compensation for expected inflation in their wage claims and in price setting.

  43. Rate of Inflation B 4 A 3 Unemployment Rate Long and short run Phillips curve(graphically) If inflation – including wage infl. - increases from 3 to 4 %, more workers will find jobs above their reservation wage and firms will increase production and employment. The economy moves from A to B. When firms and workers realise that the new nominal wages/prices are not real, employment will fall again and the economy moves to C. C

  44. Expansionary fiscal policy  increased nominal purchasing power. If firm’s believe that real demand has increased they increase production and prices. But price increases trigger an inflationary spiral: • Inflation  expectation of inflation  higher wage demands and prices  higher production costs  firms decrease production  decreased demand for labour. • Finally: The economy is back at NAIRU.

  45. During the adjustment process, therearetemporary positive effects on production and employment. • Highunemploymentlevelscanincrease NAIRU, sinceunemploymenttendsto be persistent. Thosewhohavebeenunemployed long have less chanceofreturningtoemployment. • Policies and institutions whichimprove the functioningof the economy and of the labour market canachieve a lower NAIRU.

  46. Flexibility: • Support/subsidies for labour mobility and training is one side of flexibility • Others which employers’ organisations emphasise are • Wage flexibility (differentiation & lowest level) • Employment flexibility (make temporary contracts and lay-offs easier) One example of reforms is the Danish “flexicurity”.

  47. 3. Non-market clearing (“sticky”) wages • Collective bargaining can lead to higher wages but less employment than in a perfect competition equilibrium. • Another theory of wages that explains this is the theory of efficiency wages.

  48. Efficiency wages • In the human capital model and the labour demand model, we assume that higher productivity  higher wages. • It could work the other way around too. • Workers could be more productive if they are paid better.

More Related