1 / 19

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen). Taxation and economic efficiency. LUMP SUM TAXES.

hadar
Download Presentation

The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The theory of taxation/2 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.14 Rosen) • Taxation and economic efficiency

  2. LUMP SUM TAXES • Most taxes alter relative prices and the allocation of resources introducing deadweight losses (example: the window tax in 17° century Britain induced the construction of windowless houses!!). • Only Lump sum taxesare non distortionary because they are fixed and do not depend on alterable characteristics such as wealth or income or individuals/firms behaviour. An example of non distortionary tax is a retroactive tax on last year income. But it works only once, otherwise it may affect expectations and it becomes distortionary. • If lump sum taxes can replace distortionary taxes, the government could rise more revenue without reducing the welfare of individuals. • Lump sum taxes are however very difficult to put in practice and often have negative equity effects. • They represent a benchmark to analyse the efficiency effects of taxation.

  3. Corrective taxation • Corrective taxes are those levied to correct market failures, such as negative externalities (pollution taxes, taxes on cigarettes,..). They rise revenue (and thus reduce the reliance on other taxes) and improve economic efficiency (double dividend).

  4. Taxation and Deadweight Loss/1 • The imposition of a tax introduces inefficiencies. • The Deadweight Loss (DWL) measures the magnitude of these inefficiencies, considering the distorsions created by non lump sum taxes: • Behavioural effects of taxation: individuals and firms try to avoid taxes and this affects choices related to consumption, labour supply, education, savings, investment and production are affected. • Financial effects of taxation: transactions’ forms are affected because they are treated differently (example: fringe benefit or firms’ financial structure)

  5. Taxation and Deadweight Loss/2 • Organisational effects of taxation: family formation and distribution of well being within families, firms organisation • General equilibrium effects: indirect effects of taxes on wages or on the returns of capital • Announcement effects: usually adjustment to a new tax is slow, but announcements on future taxes may affect expectations and alter the behaviour of economic individuals and firms.

  6. Taxation and Deadweight Loss/3 • A tax has two effects on the quantity demanded of the taxed good/service/factor: a) an income effect leading to a decline in the demand of all goods/services. This effect is present also with lump sum taxes and does not generate DWL because it is compensated by increased tax revenues, b) a substitution effect which induces a decline in the consumption of the taxed good relative to others, due to changes in relative prices. The DWL captures the substitution effect of taxation. • Example: if you always buy 50 apples and their price rises by 1 euro, it’s like losing 50 euro. But even if I return 50 euro to you, you will probably still buy fewer apples than before because their price has risen relative to other goods.

  7. Taxation and Deadweight Loss/4 • A tax that alter relative prices is inefficient because it lowers the individual utility more than it is necessary to raise the given amount of government revenues. • In the figure below we can get the same tax revenue AE* leaving the consumer on a higher indifference curve (with only an Income effect). • The DWL measures the excess burden of the tax and its inefficiency.

  8. Example: income and substitution effects of a sales tax on beer Total effect: from Q0 to Q1. Income effect: from Q0 to Q’ (from E to E’). Substitution effect: from Q’ to Q1 (from E’ to E*). AE* tax revenue generated by the sales tax. E*F extra tax revenue that would be generated by a lump sum tax = deadweight loss of adopting a sales tax instead of a lump sum tax. We could get the same tax revenue AE*, leaving the consumer on a higher utility curve at point E** Q other goods A E E* F Budget constraint before tax E’ E** Budget after tax Q beer Q1 Q’ Q0

  9. Taxation and Deadweight Loss/5 • For a tax on a commodity, both the income and substitution effects lead usually to a reduction in the consumption of that commodity • For a tax on interest income, the two effects have opposite sign and an ambiguous net effect: the income effect leads to an increase in savings while the substitution effect to a decrease in savings.

  10. Taxation and Deadweight loss/6Tax on labour income • A tax on labour income reduces post tax wages with an ambiguous effect on labour supply, because it depends on the relative size of the income and the substitution effects: • the income effect increases labour supply: the work effort increases as income declines, • the substitution effect reduces labour supply, since the “price” of leisure (i.e. The opportunity cost) is the income forgone for not working, this declines when post tax wage decline and thus more leisure is demanded and less time is supplied in the labour market.

  11. Taxation and economic efficiency: tax on labour If the substitution effect is larger than the income effect, taxation may have a disincentive effect on labour supply, reducing it. This effect is more likely at higher income levels. Empirical evidence shows differences between men and women: for men the two effects are of the same magnitude, so the net effect is null or very small (inelastic labour supply), while for women the substitution effect appears higher than the income effect and a decline in net wage reduces significantly their participation to the labour market (elastic labour supply).

  12. Disincentive effects of taxes on wages Income effect: from E0 to E’ (less leisure, more labour supply); Substitution effect: from E’ to E1 (more leisure and less labour supply). Net effect: from E0 to E1: lower labour supply The net effect depends on individual preferences (i.e. on the relative size of income and substitution effects). In this case the net effect is a reduction in labour supply: SE > IE. income E0 E’ E1 Pre tax budget constraint Post-tax Budget c. Leisure

  13. Deadweight Loss of taxation/7 • Adding a per unit tax T (on the producer or the consumer) increases the price and reduces the quantity traded. The efficiency loss (DWL) of the tax is determined by the reduction in quantity traded. • The loss affects both consumers and producers. • The Consumer surplus falls for two reasons: a) the consumer pays a higher price for the units still consumed, in the graph below this loss is area B b) the tax rises the price higher then the willingness to pay for some units that were previously consumed, so these units are not purchased and consumer surplus falls by area C

  14. DWL of taxation/8 • The Producer surplus falls because the quantity sold are lower than before (area E) and the price he gets for the units produced is lower (area D). • The total loss of consumers and producers in the market is the area (B+C+E+D) • This is not the overall loss for society, because the area (B +C) is government increased revenue from the tax (given by the amount of the unit tax multiplied by the quantity sold in the market when the tax is in place). The DWL is the area C+E

  15. Welfare loss with sales tax on production which increases price above the competitive price p*: Consumers pay p1 and producers get p0 p Consumer surplus: from ( A + B + C) to A c S after tax D A DWL= C + E p1 S pre-tax B C tax Tax Revenues: B + D p* D E p0 Producer surplus: F from (D + E + F) to F a 0 Q1 Q* Q

  16. DWL and demand and supply elasticities • The DWL rises with demand and supply elasticities. • If the demand curve is inelastic, consumers will buy the same quantity of the good regardless of its price and changes of prices do not distort consumption decisions. There is no DWL, because there is no change in quantity consumed. • Also if the supply curve is inelastic, the quantity produced is fixed and not affected by changes in prices and no distortions occur • If one of the curve is inelasticthere is no DWL because there is no change in quantity: • If supply is completely inelastic (vertical curve), the elasticity of demand is irrelevant • If demand is inelastic, the elasticity of supply is irrelevant.

  17. DWL and demand elasticity BEC is the DWL with the less elastic demand curve; BE’C is the DWL with the more elastic demand curve, because the reduction in Q is higher less elastic demand P Supply after tax C Supply pre tax E’ E t B Elastic demand Q

  18. Determinants of DWL • If the demand and supply curves are straight lines, the DWL can be approximated by the area of the triangle with base t and height ΔQ =(Q*-Q1): DWL = - (½) ΔQ t = (1/2)t2η Q/P • The DWL of a tax thus depends on three variables: 1. the square of the commodity tax ratet: theDWL rises with the square of the tax rate. The increase in DWL per unit increase in the tax,(i.e. the marginal DWL) rises with the tax rate: doubling of the tax rate more than doubles the DWL. High tax rates are more distortionary than low tax rates. 2. the elasticity (or flatness) of the demand and supply curvesηwhich measures how much the quantity demanded and supplied of a good/service change when its price changes: η=(ΔQ/Q)/(ΔP/P) 3. the size of the market for the taxed good/service, Q

  19. DWL increases from ABC to ADE as tax increases first by t0 and then again by t1. DBCE is the additional increase in DWL for the additional increase in t. S2 S1 p S0 t1 D t0 P2 B P1 A P0 C Demand E Q Q3 Q1 Q0

More Related