1 / 28

Optimal Pricing in a Free Market Wireless Network

6. S1. S3. S4. current $ :. current $ :. 7. S2. 5. Optimal Pricing in a Free Market Wireless Network. INFOCOM 2007. S3. ?. q 3 (t). S1. S2. q 2 (t). Michael J. Neely University of Southern California http://www-rcf.usc.edu/~mjneely.

Download Presentation

Optimal Pricing in a Free Market Wireless Network

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. 6 S1 S3 S4 current $: current $: 7 S2 5 Optimal Pricing in a Free Market Wireless Network INFOCOM 2007 S3 ? q3(t) S1 S2 q2(t) Michael J. Neely University of Southern California http://www-rcf.usc.edu/~mjneely *Sponsored in part by DARPA IT-MANET Program and NSF Grant OCE 0520324

  2. S3 ? q3(t) S1 S2 q2(t) 6 S1 S3 S4 current $: current $: 7 S2 5 Time-slotted System: t {0, 1, 2, …} Time-Varying Channels: (fading, mobility, etc.) Sn(t) = (Sn1(t), Sn2(t), …, Snk(t)) (channel states on outgoing links of node n) Transmission Rate Options (nodes use orthogonal channels): mn(t) = (mn1(t), mn2(t), …, mnk(t)) Wn(Sn(t))

  3. S3 ? q3(t) S1 S2 q2(t) 6 S1 S3 S4 current $: current $: 7 S2 5 Transmission Costs: Cntran(mn(t), Sn(t)) Example: Reception Costs: Cnbrec(mnb(t)) *Example: Cnbrec(mnb(t)) = { sb if mnb(t) > 0 { 0 if mnb(t) = 0 Cntran(m) m *this example is used in slides for simplicity

  4. S3 ? q3(t) S1 S2 q2(t) 6 S1 S3 S4 current $: current $: 7 S2 5 For simplicity of these slides: Assume single commodity (multi- source, single sink) (multi-commodity case treated in the paper) Un(t) = Queue Backlog in node n at time t Rn(t) = *New data admitted to network at source n at time t New source data R2(t) Transmit out U3(t) Endogenous arrivals Node 3 (a source) *Not all nodes are sources: Some simply act as profit-seeking relays

  5. current $: current $: S3 6 S1 S3 S4 ? q3(t) 7 S1 S2 5 S2 q2(t) For simplicity of these slides: Assume single commodity (multi- source, single sink) (multi-commodity case treated in the paper) Un(t) = Queue Backlog in node n at time t Rn(t) = *New data admitted to network at source n at time t Transmit out U5(t) Endogenous arrivals Node 5 (pure relay: not a source) *Not all nodes are sources: Some simply act as profit-seeking relays

  6. Free Market Network Pricing: revenue Data that node n already needs to deliver Advertisement current $: qn(t) expenses rec. cost: sn Node n -Each node n sets its ownper-unit price qn(t) for accepting endogenous data from others. (Seller Node Challenge: How to set the price?) -Node n advertises qn(t)and the reception cost. (fixed reception cost sb used in slides for simplicity)

  7. Advertisement Advertisement $ = qn(t) $ = qn(t) Buyer Node a Perspective Seller Node n Perspective rec = sn rec = sn Free Market Network Pricing: Node n Node a Advertisement $ = qn(t) rec = sn ? ? ? ? n b “Buyer Nodes” pay handling charge + reception fee: -Handling Charge: ban(t) = man(t)qn(t) -Reception Fee: sn

  8. Advertisement Advertisement $ = qn(t) $ = qn(t) Buyer Node a Perspective Seller Node n Perspective rec = sn rec = sn Free Market Network Pricing: Node n Node a Advertisement $ = qn(t) rec = sn ? ? ? ? n b Buyer Node Challenge: Where to send? How much to send? Is advertised price acceptable? (current transmission costs Cntran(mn(t), Sn(t)) play a role, as does the previous revenue earned for accepting data)

  9. Free Market Network Pricing: The sources’ desire for communication is the driving economic force! Modeling the Source Demand Functions: -Elastic Sources -Utility gn(r) = Source n “satisfaction” (in dollars) for sending at rate r bits/slot. h gn(r) Assumed to be: 1. Convex 2. Non-Decreasing 3. Max slope h r

  10. Node n profit (on slot t): fn(t) = total income(t) - total cost(t) - payments(t) Source (at node n) profit (on slot t): yn(t) = gn(Rn(t)) - qn(t)Rn(t) Node n Income Payments Costs Rn(t) $ = qn(t) Source at n Node n

  11. costn rn Social Welfare Definition: [gn( rn ) - costn ] Social Welfare = n where: = time avg admit rate from source n = time avg external costs expended by node n (not payment oriented) Simple Lemma: Maximizing Social Welfare… …is equivalent to maximizing sum profit (sum profit = “network GDP”) (ii)…can (in principle) be achieved by a stationary randomized routing and scheduling policy

  12. We will design 2 different pricing strategies: Stochastic Greedy Pricing (SGP): - Greedy Interpretation - Guarantees Non-Negative Profit - If everyone uses SGP, Social Welfare Maxed over all alternatives (and so Sum Profit Maxed) 2) Bang-Bang Pricing (BB): - No Greedy Interpretation - Yields a “optimally balanced” profits (profit fairness…minimizes exploitation)

  13. Prior Work: Utility Maximization for Static Networks: [Kelly: Eur. Trans. Tel. 97] [Kelly, Maulloo, Tan: J. Oper. Res. 98] [Low, Lapsley: TON 1999] [Lee, Mazumdar, Shroff: INFOCOM 2002] Utility Maximization for Stochastic Networks: [Neely, Modiano, Li: INFOCOM 2005] [Andrews: INFOCOM 2005] [Georgiadis, Neely, Tassiulas: NOW F&T 2006] [Chen, Low, Chiang, Doyle: INFOCOM 2006] Pricing plays only an indirect role in yielding max utility solution For the stochastic algorithms, dynamic “prices” do not necessarily yield the non-negative profit goal!

  14. Prior Work: Revenue Maximization for Downlinks (non-convex): [Acemoglu, Ozdaglar: CDC 2004] [Marbach, Berry: INFOCOM 2002] [Basar, Srikant: INFOCOM 2002] Markov Decision Problems for single-network owner: [Paschalidis, Tsitsiklis TON 2000] [Lin, Shroff TON 2005] Market Mechanisms: [Buttyan, Hubaux: MONET 2003] [Crowcroft, Gibbens, Kelly, Ostring WiOpt 2003] [Shang, Dick, Jha: Trans. Mob. Comput. 2004] [Marbach, Qui: TON 2005] Profit is central to problem Need a stochastic theory for market-based network economics!

  15. qn(t) = Un(t)/V Stochastic Greedy Pricing Algorithm (SGP): (Similar to Cross-Layer-Control (CLC) Algorithm from [Neely 2003] [Neely, Modiano, Li INFOCOM 2005]) For a given Control Parameter V>0… Pricing (SGP): Rn(t) Node n Admission Control (SGP): “instant utility” payment Queue Backlog Un(t) Max: gn(Rn(t)) - qn(t) Rn(t) Subj. to: 0 < Rn(t) < Rmax

  16. Stochastic Greedy Pricing Algorithm (SGP): (Similar to Cross-Layer-Control (CLC) Algorithm from [Neely 2003] [Neely, Modiano, Li INFOCOM 2005]) For a given Control Parameter V>0… Resource Allocation & Routing (SGP): Define the modified differential price Wnb(t): Wnb(t) = qn(t) - qb(t) - d/V qn(t) qb(t) where d = max[mmax out, mmax in + Rmax] Maximize: Wnb(t)mnb(t) - Cnbrec(mn(t)) - Cntran(mn(t), Sn(t)) Subj. to : mn(t) Wn(Sn(t)) b b

  17. t-1 t-1 > 0 qn(t) Rn(t) Rn(t) t-1 t=0 t=0 1 1 1 gn( ) - fn(t) > 0 t t t t=0 Theorem (SGP Performance): For arbitrary S(t) processes and for any fixed parameter V>0: Un(t) < Vh + d for all n, for all time t All nodes and sources receive non-negative profit at every instant of time t: Nodes: Sources: (a)(b) hold for any node n using SGP, even if others don’t use SGP!

  18. Theorem (SGP Performance): For arbitrary S(t) processes and for any fixed parameter V>0: Un(t) < Vh + d for all n, for all time t All nodes and sources receive non-negative profit at every instant of time t: (c) If Channel States S(t) are i.i.d. over slots and if everyone uses SGP: Social Welfare > g* - O(1/V) g* = maximum social welfare (sum profit) possible, optimized over all alternative algorithms for joint pricing, routing, resource allocation.

  19. Simulation of SGP: 6 S1 S3 S4 7 S2 5 Parameters: V= 50 Dotted Links: ON/OFF Channels (Pr[ON] = 1/2) Transmission costs = 1 cent/packet, reception costs = .5 cent/packet Solid Links: Transmission costs = 1 cent/packet Utilities: g(r) = 10 log(1 + r)

  20. 6 SGP: V=50 C2 = C5 = C7 = 1 g(r) = 10 log(1+r) S1 S3 S4 7 S2 5 Simulation of SGP:

  21. 6 SGP: V=50 C7=1 C2 = C5 = 3 g(r) = 10 log(1+r) S1 S3 S4 7 S2 5 Simulation of SGP (increase cost of C2, C5):

  22. [ Fn( fn ) + Yn( yn ) ] n Bang-Bang Pricing (BB) Algorithm: Objective is to Maximize: Where Fn(f) and Yn(y) are concave profit metrics. Yields a more balanced (and “fair”) profit distribution.

  23. Quick (incomplete) description of Bang-Bang Pricing (see paper for details):Uses General Utility Optimization technique from our previous work in [Georgiadis, Neely, Tassiulas NOW F & T 2006] BB Algorithm: Define Virtual Queues Xn(t), Yn(t) And Auxiliary Variablesgn(t), nn(t). income(t) expenses(t) + gn(t) Nodes n: Xn(t) gn(Rn(t)) payment(t) + nn(t) Sources n: Yn(t)

  24. Pricing (BB): qan(t) = { Qmax if Xa(t) < Xn(t) { 0 else (Price depends on the incoming link) Distributed Auxiliary Variable Update: Each node n solves: Maximize: VFn(g) - Xn(t)g Subject to: 0 < g < Qmax d Resource Allocation Based on Mod. Diff. Backlog: Wnb(t) = Un(t) - Ub(t) -qnb(t)[Xn(t) - Xb(t)]

  25. [ Fn( fn ) + Yn( yn ) ] n > Optimal - O(1/V) Theorem (BB Performance): If all nodes Use BB with parameter V>0, then: 1) Avg. Queue Congesetion < O(V) 2)

  26. 6 SGP: V=50 C2 = C5 = C7 = 1 g(r) = 10 log(1+r) S1 S3 S4 7 S2 5 Simulation of BB:

  27. 6 SGP: V=50 C7=1 C2 = C5 = 3 g(r) = 10 log(1+r) S1 S3 S4 7 S2 5 Simulation of BB (increase cost of C2, C5):

  28. 6 SGP: V=50 C7=1 C2 = C5 = 3 g(r) = 10 log(1+r) S1 S3 S4 7 S2 5 Conclusions: SGP: Guarantees Non-negative profit and Bounded queues, Regardless of actions of Other nodes. If all nodes Use SGP => Max sum Profit! 2) BB: Optimally Balanced, but has no greedy interpretation.

More Related