1 / 23

Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale)

Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale). Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University. Auctions with multiple indistinguishable units for sale. Examples IBM stocks Barrels of oil Pork bellies

finnea
Download Presentation

Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale)

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Multi-unit auctions & exchanges (multiple indistinguishable units of one item for sale) Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University

  2. Auctions with multiple indistinguishable units for sale • Examples • IBM stocks • Barrels of oil • Pork bellies • Trans-Atlantic backbone bandwidth from NYC to Paris • …

  3. Multi-unit auctions: pricing rules • Auctioning multiple indistinguishable units of an item • Naive generalization of the Vickrey auction: uniform price auction • If there are k units for sale, the highest k bids win, and each bid pays the k+1st highest price • Demand reduction lie [Crampton&Ausubel 96]: • k=5 • Agent 1 values getting her first unit at $9, and getting a second unit is worth $7 to her • Others have placed bids $2, $6, $8, $10, and $14 • If agent 1 submits one bid at $9 and one at $7, she gets both items, and pays 2 x $6 = $12. Her utility is $9 + $7 - $12 = $4 • If agent 1 only submits one bid for $9, she will get one item, and pay $2. Her utility is $9-$2=$7 • Incentive compatible mechanism that is Pareto efficient and ex post individually rational • Clarke tax. Agent i pays a-b • b is the others’ sum of winning bids • a is the others’ sum of winning bids had i not participated • What about revenue (if market is competitive)?

  4. Multi-unit auctions: Clearing complexity[Sandholm & Suri IJCAI-01]

  5. In all of the curves together

  6. Multi-unit reverse auctions with supply curves • Same complexity results apply as in auctions • O(#pieces log #pieces) in nondiscriminatory case with piecewise linear supply curves • NP-complete in discriminatory case with piecewise linear supply curves • O(#agents log #agents) in discriminatory case with linear supply curves

  7. Multi-unit exchanges • Multiple buyers, multiple sellers, multiple units for sale • By Myerson-Satterthwaite thrm, even in 1-unit case cannot obtain all of • Pareto efficiency • Budget balance • Individual rationality (participation)

  8. Screenshot from eMediator [Sandholm AGENTS-00]

  9. profit psell pbuy • One price for everyone (“classic partial equilibrium”): • profit = 0 • One price for sellers, one for buyers ( nondiscriminatory pricing ): profit > 0 Supply/demand curve bids profit = amounts paid by bidders – amounts paid to sellers Can be divided between buyers, sellers & market maker Quantity Aggregate supply Aggregate demand Unit price

  10. pbuy p2sell p1sell One price for each agent ( discriminatory pricing ): greater profit Nondiscriminatory vs. discriminatory pricing Aggregate demand Quantity Supply of agent 1 Supply of agent 2 Unit price psell pbuy One price for sellers, one for buyers ( nondiscriminatory pricing ): profit > 0

  11. Shape of supply/demand curves • Piecewise linear curve can approximate any curve • Assume • Each buyer’s demand curve is downward sloping • Each seller’s supply curve is upward sloping • Otherwise absurd result can occur • Aggregate curves might not be monotonic • Even individuals’ curves might not be continuous

  12. Pricing scheme has implications on time complexity of clearing • Piecewise linear curves (not necessarily continuous) can approximate any curve • Clearing objective: maximize profit • Thrm. Nondiscriminatory clearing with piecewise linear supply/demand: O(p log p) • p = total number of pieces in the curves • Thrm. Discriminatory clearing with piecewise linear supply/demand: NP-complete • Thrm. Discriminatory clearing with linear supply/demand: O(a log a) • a = number of agents • These results apply to auctions, reverse auctions, and exchanges • So, there is an inherent tradeoff between profit and computational complexity

More Related