1 / 47

Econ 522 Economics of Law

Econ 522 Economics of Law. Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 12. Monday. Reliance Investments which increase value of performance If this increases liability for breach  overreliance If it doesn’t  inefficient breach Paradox of compensation – unable to set both incentives efficiently

ezra
Download Presentation

Econ 522 Economics of Law

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Econ 522Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 12

  2. Monday • Reliance • Investments which increase value of performance • If this increases liability for breach  overreliance • If it doesn’t  inefficient breach • Paradox of compensation – unable to set both incentives efficiently • Courts compensate only for foreseeable reliance • Default Rules • Cooter and Ulen: supply rules which most parties would have wanted (efficient rules) • Ayres and Gertner: penalty defaults (penalize the parties for leaving a gap, or penalize better-informed party)

  3. Regulations

  4. Default rules versus regulations • Default rules can be contracted around • Some rules cannot • immutable rules, or mandatory rules, or regulations • Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules and regulations. • Coase: if people are rational and there are no transaction costs, private negotiations lead to efficiency • So additional regulations/limitations can only make things worse • But when people may not be rational, or when there are transaction costs or market failures, then regulations may help

  5. Discussion question • Last week: “for efficiency, enforce any contract which both the promisor and the promisee wanted to be enforceable when it was signed”

  6. Example of a regulation/immutable rule: contracts which break the law • Obvious: contract to buy a kilo of cocaine is unenforceable • Less obvious: otherwise-legal contract whose real purpose is to circumvent a law • Legal doctrine: derogation of public policy • Derogate, verb. detract from; curtail application of (a law) • Applies to contracts which could only be performed by breaking law… • …but also to “innocent” contracts whose purpose is to get around a law or regulation

  7. Derogation of public policy – example • Labor unions required by law to negotiate “in good faith” • Current NBA labor troubles • Old CBA: 57% of “basketball-related income” went to player salaries • Owners offering less than 50%, players demanding 53%... • Imagine the following contract: • “For the next 50 years, if the NBAPAaccepts a CBA paying less than 55%of BRI in player salaries, then we alsoagree that all non-retired players will work for you as coal miners everyoffseason at federal minimum wage.” • Purpose is purely to “bind hands” innegotiations with ownership • Contract would not be enforced

  8. Derogation of public policy • In general: a contract is not enforceable if it cannot be performed without breaking the law • Exception: if promisor knew (and promisee didn’t) • I’m married, my girlfriend in California doesn’t know; I promise her I’ll marry her, she quits her job and moves to Madison • My company agrees to supply a product that we can’t produce without violating a safety or environmental regulation • Keeping either promise would require breaking the law… • …but I’d still be liable for damages for breach • Like in Ayres and Gertner: default rule penalizes better-informed party for withholding information

  9. Ways to get outof a contract

  10. Formation Defenses and Performance Excuses • Formation defense • Claim that a valid contract does not exist • (Example: no consideration) • Performance excuse • Yes, a valid contract was created • But circumstances have changed and I should be allowed to not perform without penalty • Most doctrines for invalidating a contract can be explained as either… • Individuals agreeing to the contract were not rational, or • Transaction cost or market failure

  11. One formation defense: incompetence • Courts will not enforce contracts with peoplewho can’t be presumed to be rational • Children • Legally insane • Incompetence • One party was “not competent to enter intothe agreement” • No “meeting of the minds”

  12. So… • If courts won’t enforce a contract signed by someone who wasn’t competent… • What if you signed a contract while drunk? • You need to have been really, really, really drunk to get out of a contract • (“Intoxicated to the extent of being unable to comprehend the nature and consequences of the instrument he executed”) • Lucy v. Zehmer, Virginia Sup Ct 1954

  13. Lucy v. Zehmer • Zehmer and his wife owned a farm (“the Ferguson farm”), Lucy had been trying to buy it for some time • While out drinking, Lucy offers $50,000, Zehmer responds, “You don’t have $50,000” • “We hereby agree to sell to W.O. Lucy the Ferguson Farm complete for $50,00000, title satisfactory to buyer.”

  14. Lucy v. Zehmer • Zehmer and his wife owned a farm (“the Ferguson farm”), Lucy had been trying to buy it for some time • While out drinking, Lucy offers $50,000, Zehmer responds, “You don’t have $50,000” • “We hereby agree to sell to W.O. Lucy the Ferguson Farm complete for $50,00000, title satisfactory to buyer.”

  15. Lucy v. Zehmer • So, you can be pretty drunk and still be bound by the contract you signed • Might think “meeting of the minds” would be impossible • But imagine what would happen if the rule went the other way

  16. Lucy v. Zehmer • So, you can be pretty drunk and still be bound by the contract you signed • Might think “meeting of the minds” would be impossible • But imagine what would happen if the rule went the other way • Borat lawsuits • Julie Hilden, “Borat Sequel: Legal Proceedings Against Not Kazahk Journalist for Make Benefit Guileless Americans In Film” • Moral of the story: don’t get drunk with people who might ask you to sign a contract

  17. Another formation defense:dire constraints

  18. Dire constraints • Necessity • I’m about to starve, someone offers me a sandwich for $10,000 • My boat’s about to sink, someone offers me a ride to shore for $1,000,000 • Contract would not be upheld: I signed it out of necessity • Duress • Other party is responsible for situation I’m in • “I made him an offer he couldn’t refuse” • Contract signed at gunpoint would not belegally enforceable

  19. Friedman on duress • Example • Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him $100 • You write him a check • Do you have to honor the agreement? • “Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both parties wanted it to be enforceable” • He did – he wants your $100 • You did – you’d rather pay $100 than be killed • So why not enforce it? • Makes muggings more profitable  leads to more muggings • Tradeoff: refuse to enforce a Pareto-improving trade, in order to avoid incentive for bad behavior

  20. Friedman on duress • Example • Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him $100 • You write him a check • Do you have to honor the agreement? • “Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both parties wanted it to be enforceable” • He did – he wants your $100 • You did – you’d rather pay $100 than be killed • So why not enforce it? • Makes muggings more profitable  leads to more muggings • Tradeoff: refuse to enforce a Pareto-improving trade, in order to avoid incentive for bad behavior

  21. What about necessity? • Same logic doesn’t work for necessity • You get caught in a storm on your $10,000,000 sailboat • Tugboat offers to tow you to shore for $9,000,000 • (Otherwise he’ll save your life but let your boat sink) • Duress: if we enforce contract, incentive for more crimes • Here: if we enforce contract, incentive for more tugboats to be available for rescues – why is that bad? • Social benefit of rescue: value of boat, minus cost of tow • Say, $10,000,000 – $10,000 = $9,990,000 • If tugboat gets entire value, his private gain = social gain • So tugboat captain would invest the efficient amount in being available to rescue you • So what’s the problem?

  22. What about necessity? • What about your decision: whether to sail that day • 1 in 1000 chance of being caught in a storm • If so, 1 in 2 that a tugboat will rescue you • Private cost of sailing: 1 in 2000 you lose boat, 1 in 2000 you pay tugboat captain value of boat • $10,000,000/2000 + $10,000,000/2000 = $10,000 • So you’ll choose to sail if your value is above $10,000 • Social cost: 1 in 2000 boat is lost, 1 in 2000 boat is rescued • $10,000,000/2000 + $10,000/2000 = $5,005 • Efficient to sail when your value is above $5,005 • When your value from sailing is between $5,005 and $10,000, you “undersail” • If the price of being towed was just the marginal cost, your private cost = social cost and you would sail the efficient amount

  23. Friedman’s point • Same transaction sets incentives on both parties • Price that would be efficient for one decision, is inefficient for other • “Put the incentive where it would do the most good” • Least inefficient price is somewhere in the middle • And probably not the price that would be negotiated in the middle of a storm!

  24. Friedman’s point • Same transaction sets incentives on both parties • Price that would be efficient for one decision, is inefficient for other • “Put the incentive where it would do the most good” • Least inefficient price is somewhere in the middle • And probably not the price that would be negotiated in the middle of a storm! • So makes sense for courts to overturn contracts signed under necessity, replace them with ex-ante optimal terms • More general point • Single price creates multiple incentives • May be impossible to get efficient behavior in all dimensions

  25. Real duress versus fake duress • Court won’t enforce contracts signed under threat of harm • “Give me $100 or I’ll shoot you” • But many negotiations contain threats • “Give me a raise, or I’ll quit” • “$3,000 is my final offer for the car, take it or I walk” • The difference? • Threat of destruction of value versus failure to create value • A promise is enforceable if extracted as price of cooperating in creating value; not if it was extracted by threat to destroy value

  26. Example: Alaska Packers’ Association v Domenico (US Ct App 1902) • Captain hires crew in Seattle for fishing expedition to Alaska • In Alaska, crew demands higher wages or they’ll quit, captain agrees • Back in Seattle, captain refuses to pay the higher wages, claiming he agreed to them under duress • Court ruled for captain • Since crew had already agreed to do the work, no new consideration was given for promise of higher wage

  27. A performance excuse:impossibility

  28. Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility • When performance becomes impossible, should promisor owe damages, or be excused from performing? • A perfect contract would explicitly state who bears each risk • Contract may give clues as to how gaps should be filled • Industry custom might be clear • But in some cases, court must fill gap

  29. Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility • In most situations, when neither contract nor industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held liable for breach • But there are exceptions • Change “destroyed a basic assumption on which the contract was made”

  30. Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility • In most situations, when neither contract nor industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held liable for breach • But there are exceptions • Change “destroyed a basic assumption on which the contract was made” • Efficiency requires assigning liability to the party that can bear the risk at least cost • How to determine who that is?

  31. Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk? • Friedman offers several bases for making this determination • Spreading losses across many transactions • Moral hazard: who is in better position to influence outcome?

  32. Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk? • Friedman offers several bases for making this determination • Spreading losses across many transactions • Moral hazard: who is in better position to influence outcome? • Adverse selection: who is more aware of risk, even if he can’t do anything about it? • “…The party with control over some part of the production process is in a better position both to prevent losses and to predict them. It follows that an efficient contract will usually assign the loss associated with something going wrong to the party with control over that particular something.”

  33. Hadley v Baxendale • Suppose… • 80% of millers are low-damage – suffer $100 in losses from delay • 20% of millers are high-damage – suffer $200 in losses from delay • Shipper liable for actual damages • Average miller would suffer $120 in losses • Shipper makes efficient investment for average type • But not efficient for either type • Shipper liable for foreseeable damages • Shipper makes efficient investment for low-damage millers • High-damage millers have strong incentive to negotiate around default rule

  34. First midterm

  35. First Midterm • Overall very good • Mean 82, median 85 • Not assigning letter grades till end of semester, but… • to give a rough idea of how you’re doing, • based on distribution of scores on first midterm, • 70-78 would probably be a BC, 78-88 would probably be a B A-G H-M N-Z

  36. Contracts based onbad information(probably won’t get to)

  37. Misinformation • Four doctrines for invalidating a contract based on faulty information • Fraud • Failure to disclose • Frustration of purpose • Mutual mistake

  38. Fraud and Failure to Disclose • Fraud violates “negative duty” not to misinform • In some circumstances, positive duty to disclose certain information • Civil law: contract may be voided if you did not supply information you should have (“failure to disclose”) • Common law: seller is not forced to disclose everything he knows • Must warn about hidden dangers • Need not share information that makes product less valuable but not dangerous • But, new products come with “implied warranty of fitness”

  39. More on duty to disclose • Sellers must inform buyers about hidden safety risks • Common law does not generally require disclosure of other types of information • But… • Obde v Schlemeyer (1960) • Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer • Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent further damage • Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose

  40. More on duty to disclose • Sellers must inform buyers about hidden safety risks • Common law does not generally require disclosure of other types of information • But… • Obde v Schlemeyer (1960) • Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer • Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent further damage • Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose • Many states require used car dealers to reveal major repairs done, sellers of homes to reveal certain types of defects…

  41. Frustration of Purpose • Both parties based a contract on the same bad information  contract may be voided due to frustration of purpose • Coronation Cases • Rooms rented out with view of new king’s coronation parade • Parade was postponed, owners still tried to collect rent • Courts ruled change in circumstance had frustrated the purpose of the original contracts, which were therefore void • “When a contingency makes performance pointless, assign liability to the party who can bear the risk at least cost”

  42. Mutual Mistake • Frustration of purpose: circumstances changed after the contract was signed • Mutual mistake: circumstances changed before the contract was signed, but the parties didn’t know about it • Enforcing the contract would be like forcing involuntary exchange • Coase: we expect voluntary exchange to be efficient • But involuntary exchange may not be

  43. Another principle: knowledge and control • Hadley v Baxendale (miller and shipper) • Hadley knew shipment was time-critical • But Baxendale was deciding how to ship crankshaft (boat or train) • A general principle about information: efficiency generally requires uniting knowledge and control • Contracts that unite knowledge and control are generally efficient, should be upheld • Contracts that separate knowledge and control may be inefficient, should more often be set aside

  44. Unilateral mistake • Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information • Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control • Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information • I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless • You sell it to me at a low price • Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld

  45. Unilateral mistake • Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information • Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control • Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information • I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless • You sell it to me at a low price • Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld • Contracts based on unilateral mistake generally unite knowledge and control • And this creates an incentive to gather information

  46. Unilateral mistake: Laidlaw v Organ (U.S. Supreme Court, 1815) • War of 1812: British blockaded port of New Orleans • Price of tobacco fell, since it couldn’t be exported • Organ (tobacco buyer) learned the war was over • Immediately negotiated with Laidlaw firm to buy a bunch of tobacco at the depressed wartime price • Next day, news broke the war had ended, price of tobacco went up, Laidlaw sued • Supreme Court ruled that Organ was not required to communicate his information

  47. Unilateral mistake: productive versus redistributive information • Productive information: information that can be used to produce more wealth • Redistributive information: information that can be used to redistribute wealth in favor of informed party • Cooter and Ulen • Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of productive information should be enforced… • …especially if that knowledge was the result of active investment • Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of purely redistributive information, or fortuitously acquired information, should not be enforced

More Related