1 / 14

Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law

Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law. Benito ARRUÑADA (UPF) Veneta ANDONOVA (ITAM). Motivation. Previous work on property rights ( JLEO ’03): Courts end up conditioning market transition Pro-market intent & nature of civil law reform in 1800s—(e.g., mortgage market)

enid
Download Presentation

Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law Benito ARRUÑADA (UPF) Veneta ANDONOVA (ITAM)

  2. Motivation • Previous work on property rights (JLEO’03): • Courts end up conditioning market transition • Pro-market intent & nature of civil law reform in 1800s—(e.g., mortgage market) • Common / civil law divide nonexistent • Reinvigorated efficiency claims of common law (La Porta, Shleifer et al.) • GOAL: Explore an adaptation hypothesis for explaining modern Western law

  3. Analytical framework • A key design difference b/w common & civil law: allocation of rule making power to judges: • Rule making power of the whole judiciary • ‘Centralization’ of this power—binding precedent • Four areasof trade-offs: • Self-interest (1) • Information (2) • Cognitive: Rationality (allegedly decisive) • Bias and heuristics (3) • Unnaturalness of markets (4)

  4. Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (1): Self-interest • Parties • Legislators retain rulemaking supremacy • Judges do not need rules to be corrupt • Rent-seeking by parties to contracts require biased rule-maker • Depends on fields of law (?) • In private law, less legislative rent seeking • Choice of field temporary and endogenous

  5. Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (2): Lack of information • Geographic scope of markets  advantage for centralized standards (?) • But, in any case, binding precedent enough (especially if centralized) • Speed of technical change  need faster adjustment • But unclear which system adapts faster

  6. Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (3): Rationality—Biases & heuristics • Guthrie, Rachlinski & Wistrich (2001), judges fail • The same in Hindsight, Anchoring & Egocentrism  advises constraining judicial ruling—e.g., liability standards • Less in Framing & Representativeness • Doubt how judges process key experimental info • Is a defendants’ move for dismissal irrelevant when testing for anchoring effects? • Hindsight: applicable, more than to negligence, to: • Emphasis on balanced compensation ex post • Prejudice against asymmetric contracting • But affects equally judges from all jurisdictions

  7. Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (4): Rationality—Unnaturalness of markets • Sharing  redistributive rulemaking • Identifiable persons  tendency to ignore rule-setting effects of individual sentences (justice vs. efficiency) • Greater bias against abstract transactions (capital, intangibles, perhaps trade)

  8. ‘Cognitive gap’ between continental legislators and judges in 19th century • Legislators • Aristocratic democracy made ‘political leadership’ possible instead of ‘political agency’ (20th)  more ‘rational’ (pro-market) elites • Also had market experience & profit opportunities? • Judiciary • Continent: judicial nobility, more Canon law • England: former barristers

  9. Hypothesis: Western law as pro-market adaptation • Common law evolved within a slow transition to the market economy • Civil law changed from above, as part of a pro-market liberal revolution, by constraining judges rulemaking powers • Historical ‘test:’ • 19th and • 20th centuries

  10. Test: Western law in the 19th century • Few changes in common law • Needed Roman law introduced w/o codification • Binding precedent—national markets • Pro-market revolution of the civil law • Freedom of contract achieved by combining: • Codification  Default rules • Minimal judicial discretion: Sentence according to law & bound by centralized precedents • Also: Codification  doctrinal changes diluting Canon law influence: credit, penal clauses, ‘lesion’, ‘cause’ • Mandatory law to reduce transaction costs—e.g., land titling

  11. Test: Anti-market trends in Western law • Changes: statue law in ‘new’ fields and: • Common law: courts interfere with contractual freedom—e.g., unconscionability (= Canon Law) • Civil law: greater judicial discretion • Cognitive hypotheses • Increased uncertainty in 1910-30s  ‘sharing’ • Why not before? • Political change: Elites as political ‘agents’ instead of leaders • Exogenous?

  12. Alternative perspectives • The efficiency debate is not a comparative exercise analyses internal consistency, not efficiency • Comparative performance—La Porta et al. • Self-selection • Measurement nightmare • Correlation ≠ Causation • Need to • Consider self-selection • Use institutional dimensions as independent variables (e.g., judicial discretion) instead of labels (civil & common law)

  13. Concluding remarks (1) • How to create market friendly institutions—the rule of law—in transition & developing economies • Adaptation • Constrain judges—but does a cognitive gap exist? • Lack of market-wise judges • But political elites more often agents (South America) than leaders (Asian tigers) • Self-enforcing institutions • Example: community mortgage systems

  14. Concluding remarks (& 2) • How to preserve market friendly institutions in developed economies • A doses of redistribution required b/c of the cognitive anti-market bias?

More Related