340 likes | 434 Views
Explore the failures in transportation markets, learn how to fix them, discuss economic principles, and address major market failures impacting efficiency. Discover innovative solutions.
E N D
What’s wrong with transportation markets and how do we fix them? Christopher R. Knittel Department of Economics and Institute of Transportation Studies, UC Davis and NBER
Roadmap • The outcome of a well functioning market • “Thinking like an economist” • The different market failures in transportation/energy markets • How to fix them • Arguments against these fixes • Alternatives • Economics culture: please interrupt with questions or comments
The “first best” • To say a market is not working requires defining the optimum • Economists have a very specific notion of efficiency • Pareto efficiency: It is efficient, if it is not possible to reallocate resources and make one agent better off without harming another agent • Notice: nothing about equality • The idea is to maximize the size of the pie • If we don’t like the distribution of the slices, we address that through policies that don’t affect the size of the pie • These are transfers that don’t affect the actions of agents (more on this)
Market failures • If the market does not lead to a Pareto efficient outcome, we say it “fails” • It is the existence of market failures that opens the door for policymakers (and, thus governments) • Transportation markets have many failures • My plan is to discuss the main ones • Notice that this is powerful: If you can’t point to a market failure, then the market will maximize the size of the pie • Government intervention can only reduce the size (weakly)
Some principles of economics • People/society face tradeoffs • People respond to incentives • These seem obvious • People/firms think at the margin (and policymakers should too) • For example, consumers compare the cost of driving one more mile with benefit of driving one more mile • Or, firms compare the cost of selling one more gallon of gasoline with the benefit • Therefore, to influence behavior, you have change incentives “at the margin”
Trade can make everyone better off • Trade allows those firms more efficient at doing something (e.g., abatement) to do more of it • Trade maximizes the size of the pie, but doesn’t guarantee everyone gets a larger slice • The cost of something is what you give up to get it • “Opportunity costs” matter, not accounting costs
Some observations • The first best depends on the current system • The optimal transportation system if we were starting “from a clean slate” can be dramatically different compared to if we are not • This is the “at the margin” point. Sunk costs---those costs that have been incurred and cannot be recovered---do not and should not matter • So, fuels like hydrogen are (and should be) at a disadvantage, relative to starting from the beginning • The infrastructure for these fuels hasn’t been built, so these high capital costs are not sunk and should be considered • The optimal system can vary by country
If a consumer faces the true social cost of something and chooses to purchase it, then this is good for society • If you don’t agree with their decision, then either (a) you think you know more about their utility function than they do, or (b) you think their preferences are wrong • Most economists are hesitant to say (b) • Personally, I find it fairly elitist • (a) is possible if there is some lack of information, but we need to point to the information asymmetry • What does this mean? If the price of driving a Hummer included all of the social damages and someone wants to still drive it. Great!
Analyzing market failures • The ultimate goal is to understand how market failures affect efficiency and to design policies that correct these failures • Market failures come down to consumers/firms not facing the correct marginal incentives • Either prices or benefits are too high/low
Major market failures present • Externalities • Failure of agents to face “correct” costs/benefits • Network Effects/Coordination problems and investment spillovers • Failure of agents to face correct benefits • Market power • Firms pricing above their marginal cost (incorrect MB) • Asymmetric Information • Can lead to “missing” markets
The pillars of economics = marginal social cost S P First, the ideal P* = marginal social benefit D Q Q*
Negative externalities marginal social cost P = marginal private cost S DWL P* PNE = marginal social benefit D Q Q* QNE
Negative externalities in transportation • Pollution • Climate change (or risk of) • National defense • Congestion (time varying) • Accident risk (not discussed much) • In each case consumers/firms do not face the true cost of their decisions
Most frustrating part of being an economist • Solving the negative externality problem is simple • Place a tax on the item equal to the negative externality • So-called Pigouvian Tax • Advantages: • Direct, • Generates revenues, • Doesn’t require knowing Q*
Negative externalities Private cost + tax P S = marginal private cost t P* PNE = marginal social benefit D Q Q* QNE
Arguments against taxes • Political infeasible • I agree, but it remains our duty to continue to remind policymakers that it is the most direct and easiest way to solve the problem • They might be politically infeasible because we stopped doing this! • We should continue to calculate the social cost of this infeasibility • Major problem: we’re battling against oil and auto companies • Shameless cite warning: See, Fowlie, Knittel and Wolfram (2006) • Harms the poor disproportionately • Research suggests gas taxes are progressive up to the first 3 deciles, regressive from 4-10 • Remember, a tax generates revenue that can be distributed!!! • Proposition 87 was almost perfect
Arguments against taxes (cont) • Transportation demand is too inelastic for taxes to “work” • Shameless cite warning: See, Hughes Knittel and Sperling (En. Jo. fthcmg) • Notice, this just suggests that Q* and QNE are close to each other • Suggests we should look elsewhere for carbon decreases, whether we like it or not • Price inelasticity and carbon inelasticity are not equal • Suppose there was an alternative fuel that had 25% less carbon, but always costs 10 cents more than gasoline • With no carbon tax, this fuel would never be sold • Even with a vertical demand: with a carbon tax of $0.41 per gallon, we would all switch to it, drive the same number of miles and carbon would fall by 25%
Arguments against taxes (cont) • Inelastic comment continued • Long Run elasticities difficult to measure • Not a perfect experiment, but there are major differences between US and Europe • VMT: The average car is driven 22% fewer miles/year • Ownership: Europeans own 30% fewer cars/person • Fuel efficiency: European cars get 41% better MPG • Total: Europeans consume 61% fewer gallons of gas
Arguments against taxes (cont) Private cost + tax P S = marginal private cost P* t PNE D Q QNE Q*
Arguments against taxes (cont) • Requires knowing the damages • Yes. And these can be difficult to measure • What is the value of a polar bear? • But, any other policy instrument that I am aware of also requires this • And usually more • Lot’s of work on this: • Most comprehensive, Parry and Small (Am. Ec. Rev. 2006) • Risk, one paper Edlin and Mandic (J. of Pol. Economy 2006) • Congestion, lots of work • Infant Health (another warning: Knittel, Miller and Sanders [2008])
A nice alternative • An alternative to a tax is a cap and trade system • For example, gasoline refiners can face an aggregate carbon cap and be required to have a permit for every unit of carbon they “create” • They would then trade among each other • Very common in pollution market • The basis for Europe’s Kyoto compliance strategy, Northeastern NOx market for powerplants, CA’s RECLAIM market for NOx, Australia carbon market, etc.
Cap and trade • Why so common? • Not a tax • Permits are typically allocated in political way • This lessons the effect on firms and some firms can even profit • This gets the firms “on board” • Good thing: marginal incentives are independent of the initial allocation • First best is possible • Can tighten the cap until the permit price equals the negative externality
Cap and trade and S and D P marginal private cost PCAP PNE Permit Price = marginal social benefit D Q QCAP QNE
Arguments against cap and trade • Positive demand shocks can lead extreme prices • Australia’s solution -- cap the permit price at some level • In fact, you could cap it at the level of the externality! • We’re back to the tax solution • Effectively, this allows for an infinite number of permits at that price • Transportation demand is inelastic • See above. • Can’t have a cap on each driver • But, you can set it at the refinery level (for carbon) • For other pollutants, such as NOx, would require making assumptions on “typical” driving habits
Alternatives • Pollution: technology forcing (standards) • National defense: CAFE standards, LCFS, subsidies (negative taxes) • Climate Changes: LCFS, subsidies • Congestion: HOV lanes
New development in CA • LCFS exciting new development • Firms face a carbon intensity rate constraint • Holland, Knittel and Hughes (2007) work through the incentives of the firms: • Essentially: taxes fuels with carbon intensities above the standard, but subsidizes fuels with CIs below • All this is internal to the firm, so we never have to say “Taxx” • Can get the relative prices “right,” but low carbon fuels will be too cheap • Used as to solve other market failures?
(Indirect) network effects • So-called chicken and egg problem • E.g., hydrogen automakers need hydrogen refueling stations, hydrogen refueling stations need hydrogen automobiles • Exists in many industries – any hardware/software industry • Blueray/HD-DVD player manufacturers need content, content providers need players • This is the reason why Betamax died! • Mall store #1, needs mall store #2, and vice versa • Here, fixing the prices may not be enough (not completely true)
= marginal social cost S P P* marginal social benefit = marginal private benefit D Q Q* QNet
What do we learn? • Network effects can lead us to get “stuck” at a non-optimal equilibrium (Windows?) • We can also switch to a non-optimal equilibrium • Largely depends on consumers’ expectations • How do we solve them? • They occur because each side of the market doesn’t “internalize” the benefit to the other side • The obvious solution is for the two sides to “merge” • Alternatives: • They can coordinate, policymakers can set up consortia • Policymakers can set mandates • Suboptimal prices
Market power – the good market failure? • In almost every other industry, the market failure we worry about most is market power • Market power occurs when a firm’s output decision influences price • When this is the case, the firm no longer views its marginal revenue (revenue from selling one additional unit) as equal to the price • Why? Because in order to sell one more unit, the firm must lower the price on all of the existing units • Market power drives a wedge between price the social marginal cost; the supply curve is no longer the MC curve • So, we have “deadweight loss” from under consumption
Sources of market power in transportation • OPEC/Extraction • Cartels exist to increase market power • Shipping (?) • Refinery Industry • Retail Industry (probably small) • In theory, market power and negative externalities can fully offset each other • For example, if P=60, MPC=10, Negative Externality=50
Where do we go from here? • Unfortunately, the easiest and most direct way to solve many of the problems inherent in energy markets may not be politically feasible • But, we shouldn’t stop trying • Most of the alternatives create perverse incentives somewhere • (If not, they would be the preferred choice) • These perverse effects require additional policies, which… • We can’t lose trust in markets • Energy markets are failing, for the most part, because the prices are wrong • We can’t use arguments like “they’ve never worked in the past, so they won’t work in the future”