1 / 17

Economics 434 Theory of Financial Markets

Economics 434 Theory of Financial Markets. Professor Edwin T Burton Economics Department The University of Virginia. Finite State Approach. Usually we assume an infinite number of states of the world ( uncountably infinite, in fact)

Download Presentation

Economics 434 Theory of Financial Markets

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Economics 434Theory of Financial Markets Professor Edwin T Burton Economics Department The University of Virginia

  2. Finite State Approach • Usually we assume an infinite number of states of the world (uncountably infinite, in fact) • Instead, image that we can identify and list each possible state of the world that may occur next period: e.g. recession, slow growth, boom times, etc. • Then, imagine that securities are defined by what they pay in each possible state of the world

  3. Finite States of the World States: S1 S2 S3 Prob of States: π1π2π3 Securities: B1 B2 B3

  4. Dividend Payoffs States 1 2 3 Securities 1 D11 D12 D13 2 D21 D22 D23 3 D31 D32 D33

  5. Security Prices P1 P2 P3

  6. A Portfolio (ϴ1, ϴ2, ϴ3) V = Value of a portfolio: ϴ1P1 +ϴ2P2 + ϴ3P3 {In matrix notation, this is simply ϴP, where ϴis a row vector and P is a three by one column vector}

  7. What about security returns? For state 1 occurs: Security 1 will pay D11 Security 2 will pay D21 Security 3 will pay D31 A portfolio with quantities of securities: (ϴ1, ϴ2, ϴ3) Pays ϴ1D11 + ϴ2D21 + ϴ3D31 if state 1 occurs

  8. For each state, the ϴ portfolio returns are given as: • Pays ϴ1D11 + ϴ2D21 + ϴ3D31 if state 1 occurs • Pays ϴ1D12+ ϴ2D22+ ϴ3D32if state 2 occurs • Pays ϴ1D13+ ϴ2D23+ ϴ3D33if state 3 occurs In matrix notation: Returns = ϴD where ϴis a row vector And D is a three by three matrix

  9. A Portfolio that Always Makes Money is a ϴ such that • ϴ1D11 + ϴ2D21 + ϴ3D31>= 0 • ϴ1D12+ ϴ2D22+ ϴ3D32 >= 0 • ϴ1D13+ ϴ2D23+ ϴ3D33 >= 0 • And, at least one of the above is > 0 (not = 0) • {In matrix notation, this is the situation when ϴD > 0, where ϴ is a one by three row vector, D is a three by three matrix, and the product of the two is a one by three row vector}

  10. Arbitrage exists when there is a ϴ such that The value of the portfolio is less than or equal to zero and the portfolio never loses money and always makes a profit in at least one state. If ϴP ≤ 0 then ϴD > 0 Or If ϴP < 0 then ϴD ≥ 0

  11. Assume No Arbitrage Opportunities Exist If ϴD > 0 which means that the portfolio never loses money and makes money in at least one state of the world Then ϴP > 0, meaning that the portfolio must involve a positive investment This means that you cannot make a profit without putting up money.

  12. So, what can we conclude if there are no arbitrage opportunities? • First, we can conclude that there is a set of prices: Ψ1, Ψ2, Ψ3 (all ≥ 0) such that: P1 = Ψ1D11 + Ψ2D12+ Ψ3D13 P2= Ψ1D21+ Ψ2D22+ Ψ3D23 P3= Ψ1D31+ Ψ2D32+ Ψ3D33 These Ψi’s are state prices (the marginal cost of obtaining additional dollar in state i

  13. Now convert state prices to probabilities: Define: Ψ = Ψ1+ Ψ2+ Ψ3 Define πi = Ψi / Ψ Then π1+ π2+π3 = 1 These can be thought of as probabilities of state one, two and three occurring. They are not the true probabilities, though. They are known as “risk-adjusted” probabilities.

  14. Now, using π’s, we can rewrite: P1 = Ψ1D11 + Ψ2D12+ Ψ3D13 P2= Ψ1D21+ Ψ2D22+ Ψ3D23 P3= Ψ1D31+ Ψ2D32+ Ψ3D33 as P1 =Ψ{π1D11+ π2D12+ π3D13} P2 = Ψ{π1D21+ π2D22+ π3D23} P3 = Ψ{π1D31+ π2D32+ π3D33} Note that the prices seem equal to “expected value” of dividends where probabilities are the πi’s (except for the role of Ψ)

  15. How to interpret Ψ? • Suppose there is some ϴR with the property that: • ϴ1RD11+ ϴ2RD21+ ϴ3RD31 = 1 • ϴ1RD12+ ϴ2RD22+ ϴ3RD32 = 1 • ϴ1RD13+ ϴ2RD23+ ϴ3RD33 = 1 • Which means ϴRis a riskfree portfolio (asset) • Then: • Ψ = ϴ1Rp1+ ϴ2Rp2+ ϴ3Rp3 • Today’s value of the riskless porfolio • Then any security’s price = discounted expected return, where the • discount is Ψ and the probabilities are π’s (risk adjusted probabilities)

  16. Second Mid Term Thursday, Nov 8 • Will Cover • Markowitz • Tobin • CAPM • Beginnings of State Price Approach • Will Not Cover • State prices • Risk adjusted probabilities • No class on Tuesday, Nov 6th(election day)

  17. The End

More Related