1 / 30

Assessing the Poverty Impact of Economic Growth: The Case of Indonesia

Assessing the Poverty Impact of Economic Growth: The Case of Indonesia. B. Essama-Nssah and Peter J. Lambert World Bank Poverty Reduction Group and University of Oregon October, 2006. Introduction. Context Poverty Reduction: A fundamental objective of development (MDGs)

deepak
Download Presentation

Assessing the Poverty Impact of Economic Growth: The Case of Indonesia

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Assessing the Poverty Impact of Economic Growth:The Case of Indonesia B. Essama-Nssah and Peter J. Lambert World Bank Poverty Reduction Group and University of Oregon October, 2006

  2. Introduction • Context • Poverty Reduction: • A fundamental objective of development (MDGs) • Hence we need • a metric for assessing effectiveness in terms of this objective. • meaningful ways to assess poverty impact of shocks and policies. • Economic growth: • Potentially a powerful instrument of poverty reduction. • Yet, same rate of growth can lead to different levels of poverty reduction in different circumstances. • Issue • When to declare a growth pattern pro-poor?

  3. General approach • Logic of social impact evaluation understood as an assessment of changes in individual and social welfare attributable to a shock or policy. • Three basic dimensions: • Identification of individual situations. • Aggregation of individual situations into an indicator of a social state. • Ranking of social states

  4. Specification • Identification: • Individual situations represented by point elasticity of income w.r.t. a change in aggregate income. • Aggregation: • Use members of the class of additively separable poverty measures (e.g. Watts, FGT). • Ranking: • A pro-poor growth pattern achieves a reduction in poverty over and above that which is feasible in a benchmark case (either desirable or counterfactual). • We choose as benchmark the amount of poverty reduction attainable under distributional neutrality (equiproportionate growth).

  5. Case of Indonesia • A long reputation of high achievements in growth and poverty reduction, even in the face of adverse conditions (Ravallion and Huppi 1991; World Bank 1996). • Is the observed poverty reduction more or less than we would have observed had growth been distributionally neutral? • We answer this question using 1993-2002 data. • We also unbundle the pattern of growth, to identify the contributions of income components to the overall outcome.

  6. Focus of the rest of the presentation: • Evaluation Framework • A General Impact Indicator • Poverty Focus • Empirical Results • Data • Profile of Poverty and Inequality • Pro-Poorness • Conclusion

  7. Evaluation Framework • Identification • Let x be an individual characteristic (e.g. income) that is responsive to growth (or policy change). • Let f(x) be the frequency density function for x among the population. • Let u(x) be any individual attribute (e.g. poverty), a function of x.

  8. Aggregation • Average x: • Average u(x) : • Impact • Growth rate of mean of x: • Growth pattern (elasticity of individual income with respect to y): • q(x) is a normalized growth incidence curve (Ravallion & Chen, 2003).

  9. Impact, continued • Change in average u(x) induced by change in y: • As a proportion: • As an elasticity: • Component breakdown(x=x1 +x2  xq(x)=x1 q(x1)+x2 q(x2)):

  10. Poverty Focus • x is now income or expenditure and mx is the poverty line, call it z. • The function is an indicator of individual deprivation. • Overall poverty

  11. Poverty Impact • Aggregate poverty elasticity: - Decomposition by income components:

  12. Indicator of pro-poorness: • where q0 is the growth pattern associated with distribution neutrality, i.e. q0(x) = 1 for all x. - Indicator measures the difference between poverty reduction under distribution neutrality and amount produced by observed growth pattern. - Typically, the growth elasticity ΦP(q) is negative, since positive growth induces poverty reduction for all incomes below the poverty line. • If the pro-poorness indexπP(q) is positive, the observed growth pattern leads to more poverty reduction than the benchmark case

  13. Factoring growth into scale and distribution contributions Elasticity: Pro-poorness: • growth is pro-poor if distributional component of poverty elasticity is negative.

  14. Ratio Comparisons • Instead of an additive comparison, one can consider the ratio of the actual elasticity to the benchmark elasticity. Growth is pro-poor if this ratio is greater than 1. • Ratio comparison for Watts index leads to Ravallion and Chen’s (2003) “mean growth rate for the poor” measure • Ratio comparisons also underlie the Kakwani et al (2004) measure called “poverty equivalent growth rate”. • Decomposability not established for ratio measures

  15. Empirical Results • Two types of datasets for Indonesia used in this study • Distribution of household expenditure per decile (in 1993 PPP dollars) from World Bank Global Poverty Monitoring database. • SUSENAS household surveys (1999, 2002) used to achieve decomposition of pro-poorness across income/expenditure components • Poverty line: about 2 dollars a day.

  16. Poverty and Inequality in Indonesia • 1993-1996 • Poverty falls while inequality increases. • Likely outcome of successful adjustment to oil shock • 1996-1999 • Poverty increases while inequality falls • Likely outcome of the 1997 Asian financial crisis. • 1999-2002 • Poverty falls, inequality goes up. • Signs of recovery: macroeconomic stability associated with reduced vulnerability to external shocks.

  17. Profile of Poverty and Inequality in Indonesia, continued

  18. Pro-Poorness in Indonesia • Additive comparisons • Ratio Comparisons

  19. Growth pattern in Indonesia for 1999-2002

  20. Components of growth for 1999-2002

  21. Pro-poorness components in Indonesia for 1999-2002

  22. Distributional component of growth Shapley Decomposition • distributional effect alleviated some of the negative impact of the 1997 economic crisis.

  23. Component Analysis, 1999-2002 • Outcome driven mainly by what happened to expenditure on rice, with some help from expenditure on other food items. • Rice represents 26 percent of total expenditure for the poor. • Total food expenditure including rice is about 73 percent of total household expenditure for the poor.

  24. Winners and losers among the poor • Actual growth pattern for 1999-2002 crosses benchmark pattern twice before the headcount ratio (55 percent). • q(x) below benchmark up to 20th percentile, and between 43rd and 55th percentiles (these are the losers) • winners located between 20th and 43rd percentiles.

  25. Appraisal of gains and losses • Pro-poorness at percentiles:

  26. The gains versus the losses • Percentile pro-poorness curves lie below zero: economic growth not pro-poor at any percentile up to the headcount. • according to our metric, benefits enjoyed by the poor between the 20th and the 43rd percentiles not high enough to compensate for losses experienced by those who came before.

  27. Conclusions • Pro-poor growth analysis fits nicely within the logic of social evaluation • An assessment of changes in individual and social welfare attributable to the process of economic growth. • Measurements depend critically on underlying value judgments. • Our metric for pro-poorness is defined by the following choices: • (1) individual outcomes represented by point elasticity of income; • (2)social welfare measured by poverty measures in the additively separable class; • (3) standard of comparison based on distributional neutrality.

  28. Application of this approach to data for Indonesia reveals that: • Overall poverty reduction achieved over period 1993-2002 far below what distributionally neutral growth would have achieved. • Focusing on the 1999-2002 period: • Some poor people gained from the economic growth that occurred over that period, but these gains do not measure up to the losses suffered by the rest of the poor. • The behavior of categories of expenditures over the same period reveals that the weak performance is due mainly to changes in food expenditure.

  29. References • Essama-Nssah, B. (2005). A unified framework for pro-poor growth analysis. Economics Letters, vol. 89, pp. 216-221. • Essama-Nssah, B. and Lambert P.J. (2006). Measuring the Pro-Poorness of Income Growth within an Elasticity Framework. World Bank Policy Working Paper No. 4035 (October) • Kakwani, N.C., S. Khandker and H.H. Son (2004). Pro-poor growth: concepts and measurement with country case studies. Working Paper Number 2004-1, International Poverty Center, Brasil. • Kraay, Art. (2006). When is growth pro-poor? Evidence from a panel of countries Journal of Development Economics 80, 198-227. • Ravallion, Martin and Huppi Monika. 1991. Measuring Changes in Poverty: A Methodological Case Study of Indonesia during an Adjustment Period. The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 5, No. 1:57-82. • Ravallion, M. and S. Chen (2003). Measuring pro-poor growth. Economics Letters, vol. 78, pp. 93-99. • World Bank (1996). Indonesia: dimensions of growth. Report No.15383-IND. Country Department III, East Asia and Pacific Region. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

  30. End.

More Related