1 / 33

Standard Approaches for Insurance Risk Pricing

The Cost of Conditional Risk Financing CAS Ratemaking Seminar March 11-12, 2004 Frank Schnapp National Crop Insurance Services, Inc. Standard Approaches for Insurance Risk Pricing. Economic methods Adopts Risk-taker’s perspective Expected Utility Theory Key concept: Preferences

davidi
Download Presentation

Standard Approaches for Insurance Risk Pricing

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Cost of Conditional Risk FinancingCAS Ratemaking SeminarMarch 11-12, 2004Frank SchnappNational Crop Insurance Services, Inc.

  2. Standard Approaches for Insurance Risk Pricing • Economic methods • Adopts Risk-taker’s perspective • Expected Utility Theory • Key concept: Preferences • Shape of utility function is unknown • Ignores the insurer’s ability to reduce risk through diversification • Financial methods • Takes Investor’s perspective • Net Present Value model • Key concept: Cost of capital • Capital is invested at the time an insurance policy is issued • Focus is on timing of cash flows • Ignores the uncertainty of the cash flows

  3. Proposed Risk Pricing ModelBasic Concepts • Adopts the Risk taker’s perspective • No capital is needed to issue an additional policy • Considers both the uncertainty and timing of cash flows • Based on real costs • Expected Utility Theory is preference based • Cost of capital represents a competitive return, not an actual cost • Risk diversification (pooling) • Reduces insurer’s risk • May (or may not) affect the price paid by policyholder • Insurer operates under a Capital Preservation Objective

  4. Risk Taker’s Perspective • Return to the insurer  Return to the investor • Company actions to provide an adequate return to investor: • Increase or decrease expenses • Commissions, salaries, bonuses • Portfolio selection • Pursue markets where Insurer has a competitive advantage • Higher risk markets producer higher returns • Increase or decrease amount of insurance or investment risk

  5. Two Varieties of Pricing Model • Based on Actual costs  Retroactive pricing • Based on Expected costs  Prospective pricing

  6. No Capital is needed to issue an additional policy • Capital is used when a claim is paid • And only if the Damages exceed the Premium • If Damages < Premium  Insurer earns a profit • If Damages > Premium  Insurer contributes capital • Capital contribution = max(Damages – Premium, 0) • Takes into account the uncertainty of the outcomes • Analysis is similar if expenses are included

  7. Insurance as a Risk Financing Mechanism • Self-insurance • Self-insurer borrows funds to pay any deficit on policy • Repays the loan over time • Purchase of an insurance policy • Insurer provides funds as needed to pay any deficit on policy • Insurer functions as the “Bank” • Risk financing is treated as a loan, not as an investment • Insurer’s Capital Preservation Objective • Insurer needs to recover the borrowed funds • Loan can be repaid by: • Policyholder, or • All policyholders in the market segment • Policyholders in all market segments

  8. Retroactive Pricing (Payback) Method1st Example: Premium = Expected Damages • Return = Profit • Deficit = Amount of Capital consumed • Outcomes A & B – Insurer earns a profit • Premium in year 2 is $1000 = Expected damages • Outcome C – Insurer makes a capital contribution (loan) of $2000 • Loan must be repaid by next expected occurrence in 4 years = 1/.250 • Annual payment on loan = $500 • Premium in Years 2-5 = Expected Damages + Annual Payment on Loan = $1500 • Premium may change again if outcome C occurs in years 2, 3, or 4 • Long term average premium > $1000

  9. Retroactive Pricing (Payback) Method2nd Example: Premium = $1400 • Assume outcome C occurs every 4th year • Insurer makes $1600 capital contribution every 4th year • Policyholder contributes $400 expected profit every year • Total of $1600 over four years • Policyholder pays for the insurer’s capital contributions (over the long term) • Result represents the “optimal” retroactive premium • Premium will vary depending on the actual outcome

  10. The “Optimal” Retroactive Price • Policyholder pays for potential use of the insurer’s capital • Pays the long term average cost • Premium = Expected Damages + Average cost of loan • Cost based surcharge si on loan of xi – P • Term of loan is 1/pi • si represents the interest charged on the loan • si is reduced for the time value of money • si >= 1 • Equivalent to the Prospective price for the exposure • Insurer charges for its expected, not actual, capital contribution • No recognition of the effect of Insurer’s risk diversification • Can be interpreted as the Self-insurance price P = E(X) + xi>P(xi – P)sipi

  11. Retroactive vs. Prospective Pricing • Prospective method • Useful for small exposures • Used if Insurer is not permitted to recoup losses from policyholder • Cost of loan may be spread across all exposures in market segment • Retroactive pricing • For exposures large enough to be self-rated • Reinsurance and large accounts

  12. Retroactive Pricing and the Insurance Market Pricing Cycle • Insurers raise prices to recoup underwriting losses • High prices would continue even if coverage is amended • Terrorism, toxic mold coverage • Enables insurers to “recoup” capital losses in subsequent years • Enhances long term solvency of the industry • Supports Capital Preservation Objective

  13. Insurance Market Pricing Cycle Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry. Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/

  14. Hard Markets Follow Years of Deteriorating Results Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry. Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/

  15. The Effect of Risk Diversification (Pooling) on Price • Evaluate Risk from a portfolio perspective • Effect of Risk diversification within a market segment • Reduces an insurer’s average risk per exposure: • V(Ž) = V(Z) / n • Permits the insurer to reduce its risk margin on each exposure • Competition may prevent Insurer from pricing an exposure for its own risk • Price each market segment for its own risk instead • Effect of Risk diversification across market segments • No reduction in the insurer’s price (mostly) • Reduces the insurer’s risk instead

  16. Example of Risk Diversification Across Market Segments (Without Price Reduction) • Assume Insurer prices each market segment for its own risk • Distribution A: Single market segment • Insurer frequently uses its own capital • Distribution B: Portfolio consisting of 5 market segments • Insurer occasionally uses its own capital • Distribution C: Portfolio consisting of 12 market segments • Insurer rarely, if ever, uses its own capital • A loss in one market segment is paid by the policyholders in other market segments • Affects si, the cost of borrowed funds • Helps satisfy the Insurer’s Capital Preservation Objective

  17. Illustration of Risk Diversification without Price Reduction

  18. Prospective Pricing Model with Risk DiversificationAcross Market Segments • Risk Pricing Model • Assumes insurer rarely, if ever, uses its own capital • Allows insurer to use a uniform surcharge for si of a >= 1 • For a very well-diversified insurer, a = 1 • Select a to satisfy Capital Preservation Objective • Price achieves a balance between Risk and Return • For outcome xi, define Return as P – xi • Define Risk as (xi – P)si or (xi – P)a for xi > P, else 0 • The premium P is the unique solution to: P – E(X) = ax>P (x – P) dF(x) Expected Risk = Expected Return

  19. Comparison to Expected Utility Theory • Risk Pricing Model is consistent with Utility pricing • Model is applied to market segments, not to individual exposures • Shape of Utility function: • Two rays with positive slope meeting at 0 • Concave downward • “Utility” is independent of wealth • Risk aversion parameter is a function of insurer’s diversification • Consistent with pricing formulas: • P(c) = c • P(X + c) = P(X) + c • P(aX) = aP(X) for a >= 0 • P(X + Y) <= P(X) + P(Y) (diversification property) • For X ~ N(m,s2), P(X) = m + ls (with l a constant) • Income taxes have little or no effect on price

  20. The Mutually Acceptable Price • Insurer’s price declines as number of exposures increases • Enables Insurer to compete with self-insurance • Even if the Insurer is more “risk averse” than the Self-insurer • No mutually acceptable price exists if insurer’s expenses are too high

  21. Competitive Market Pricing • Construct Supply and Demand curves for insurance • Limits on the Insurer’s ability to insure additional policies: • Quality of the Insurer’s book declines during rapid expansion • Staffing is insufficient to handle the work load • But: the amount of Capital held by Insurer is not a limitation • Intersection of Supply & Demand determines the market price • Low cost Insurers earn more than a “normal” profit • High cost Insurers earn less than a “normal” profit • Will continue to write insurance as long as variable costs are met • Decision to participate in market is unrelated to Cost of Capital

  22. Is the Capital Preservation Objective Realistic? • U.S. P&C insurance industry is consistently profitable • Only one exception • 2001 (9/11 terrorist attack) • Sharp increase in insurance prices immediately afterward • Helped industry to recoup losses from event • Stability: Insolvency rate remarkably low • Ten year average = 0.72% • Most insolvencies are small, low rated companies • Industry structure • Unconcentrated, with a large number of competitors • Survival & profitability much better than auto, steel, & airlines

  23. World Trade Center (9/11) Andrew Northridge $28 Billion full year P&C Industry Profitability Based on “Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry.” Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/

  24. P&C Industry Insolvency Rates Overview & Outlook for the Property/Casualty Insurance Industry. Dr. Robert P. Hartwig. July, 2003. Insurance Information Institute. http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/industryoutlook/

  25. Summary • Retroactive Pricing • Reinsurance, large accounts, Insurance Market Pricing Cycle • Prospective Pricing • Without risk diversification • Each exposure is priced for its own risk (e.g., self-insurance) • With risk diversification • Insurer determines its price for each market segment, not each exposure • Diversification across market segments minimizes use of insurer’s capital • Price is determined from Risk-taker perspective • Cost of capital is not relevant to the model • Model accounts for: • Risk/Return tradeoff, Expenses, Taxes, Time value of money • Competition, Self-insurance, Heterogeneity of exposures • Investment Income on insurance cash flows • Unified treatment of insurance and investment pricing

  26. Additional Topics

  27. Pricing for Systematic Risk(Once the Insurer determines the premium it needs for a market segment, how does it determine its price for each policy?) • Let X1, … Xn be exposures in market segment W = Xi • Assume prices are additive: P(Xi+Xk;W) = P(Xi;W) + P(Xk;W) • Assume the price PW for the market segment W is known • Let Price be based on Xi’s contribution to systematic risk W • Xi can be uniquely decomposed as b W + Ui • With b = cov(Xi,W) / V(W) • Systematic risk component is b W • Diversifiable risk component is Ui (since Ui = 0) • Ui is uncorrelated with W • Systematic Risk Pricing Model: P(Xi;W) = E(Xi) + b (PW - E(W))

  28. Observations on Systematic Risk Pricing Model • Market segment premium PW can be selected arbitrarily • It need not be determined using the Risk Pricing Model • Restriction: E(W) <= PW <= P(Xi) • Application to Insurance pricing • Accounts for systematic risk • Price is unrelated to security market returns • Formula can be converted to a rate of return on price • Formula does not involve capital • Finding: Rate of return formula is identical to the CAPM formula

  29. Application to Security Market Pricing • Model can be applied to determine security prices • Not rates of return • Price is tied to the underlying earnings of the business • Consistent with Dividend Discount Model • But, it recognizes the uncertainty of the dividends • Relationship to Rate of Return • Model determines rate of return on price, not on capital • Finding: The CAPM does not apply to security market pricing • Reason: A security is tied to the earnings of a business • But, a business need not have a fixed risk exposure over time • A company can enter or leave markets, change its pricing, etc. • CAPM is consistent with the model under narrow restrictions

  30. Comparison of the Role of Capital • Risk Pricing Model • Capital expenditure is no different from any other cash flow • Purchase of productive goods: Capital investment = Up-front Expense (fixed) • Purchase of a security: Capital expenditure = Price (may be negotiable) • Analysis of an investment depends on the responsibility for losses • A business pays for operating losses out of its capital • A security holder has no obligation to use its capital to pay losses • Insurance: Other policyholders provide the capital needed to settle claims • Systematic Risk Pricing Model and the Revised CAPM • Capital has no bearing on price • Rate of return is defined in relation to price, not capital • Actuarial Pricing Models (per Standards of Practice) • Cost of Capital is fundamental

  31. Pricing of Uncertain Future Damages • Assume stable risk aversion parameters over time: a1 = a0 • Justification: a = 1 for a well-diversified insurer • Given X0 and X1 with identical damage distributions • Damages are paid at times 0 and 1, respectively • Since a is constant, P1(X1) = P0(X0) • What is the price at time 0 for future damages X1? • Let v be the discount factor corresponding to the risk-free rate • Discount the future price for X1 to time 0 = vP1(X1) • Or, discount each outcome to time 0 = P0(vX0) • Both methods give the same price: • P0(vX0) = vP1(X1)

  32. The Time Value of Money • Risk-free rate • Assume Lender’s objective is to maintain purchasing power • Purchasing power is affected by future inflation • Future inflation is uncertain • Define the risk-free rate as the price needed to offset the risk of future inflation • Apply risk vs. return analysis to future purchasing power • Example: model inflation as a Markov chain • Shape of yield curve: • Short term rate is similar to expected inflation rate • Increases as payment horizon increases • Long term rate stabilizes after several periods

  33. End of Presentation

More Related