1 / 35

Algorithmic Game Theory and Internet Computing

Algorithmic Game Theory and Internet Computing. Computation of Competitive Equilibria. Amin Saberi Stanford University. Outline. History Economic theory and equilibria (existence, dynamics, stability) An algorithmic approach: computation, polynomial time computability. A bit history.

carl
Download Presentation

Algorithmic Game Theory and Internet Computing

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Algorithmic Game Theoryand Internet Computing Computation of Competitive Equilibria Amin Saberi Stanford University

  2. Outline • History • Economic theory and equilibria (existence, dynamics, stability) • An algorithmic approach: computation, polynomial time computability

  3. A bit history • Rabbi Samuel ben Meir (12th century, France): 2nd century text: “You shall have inspectors of weights and measures but not inspectors of prices.” Commentary (Aumann): If one seller charges too high a price, then another will undercut him. • Adam Smith (1776): Capital flows from low-profit to high-profit industries (demand function implicit?)

  4. The beginning of analytical work • Standard analysis • demand functions: Cournot (1838) • supply functions: Jenkin (1870) • excess demand: Hicks (1939). • Dynamics in 1870’s: Is out-of-equilibrium behavior modeled by demand and supply?

  5. Walras, Fisher, Pareto, Hicks • Walras [1871, 1874]: first formulator of competitive general equilibrium theory. Recognized need for stability (how to get into equilibrium)His name: tatonnements (gropings).

  6. Walras, Fisher, Pareto, Hicks • Walras [1871, 1874]: first formulator of competitive general equilibrium theory. Recognized need for stability (how to get into equilibrium)His name: tatonnements (gropings). • Fisher (1891): tried to compute the equilibrium prices

  7. First computational approach! • Fisher (1891): Hydraulic apparatus for calculating equilibrium

  8. Walras, Fisher, Pareto, Hicks • Walras [1871, 1874]: tatonnements • Pareto (1904): Pointed out that even a simple economy requires a large set of equations to define equilibrium. Argued that market was an effective way to solve large systems of equations, better than an “ordinateur” (his word in the French translation). I believe this is the word now used to translate, “computer.”

  9. Walras, Fisher, Pareto, Hicks • Walras [1871, 1874]: tatonnements • Fisher (1894), Pareto (1904): Markets and computation • Hicks (1939): convergence and “Hicksian” condition on the Jacobian of the excess demand functions (the determinants of the minors be positive if of even order and negative if of odd order)

  10. Samuelson and successors • Samuelson [1944]: Hicksian conditions neither necessary nor sufficient for stability. • Metzler [1945]: if off-diagonal elements of Jacobian are non-negative (commodities are gross substitutes), then Hicksian conditions are sufficient. • Arrow [1974]: Hicksian conditions were actually equivalent to the statement that the real roots of the Jacobian are negative.

  11. Arrow, Debreu and… • Arrow-Hurwicz et. al. papers [1977]: Sufficient conditions for stability of Samuelson-Lange systemGross substitution implies that Euclidean norm decreases Will talk about these dynamics in details in the next lecture • Arrow-Debreu: existence of equilibrium prices (will show a variation of Debreu’s proof)

  12. End of the program? • Scarf’s example, Saari-Simon Theorem: For any dynamic system depending on first-order information (z) only, there is a set of excess demand functions for which stability fails. • Uzawa: Existence of general equilibrium is equivalent to fixed-point theorem (will show in this lecture) • Linear complementarity Programs (LCP) and algorithms:Scarf, Eaves, Cottle…(later in the quarter)

  13. Outline • History • Economic theory and equilibria (existence, dynamics, stability) • An algorithmic approach: computation, polynomial time computability

  14. Last 10 years • New applications: Internet, Sponsored search, combinatorial auctions • Computation as a lense! • First papers: Megiddo 80’s, DPS 01prices and ND communication complexity • Lots of new algorithm: convex programs combinatorial algorithms

  15. A CES Market • n buyers, with specified money • m divisible goods (unit amount) • Buyers have CES utility functions: Contains several interesting special cases:  = 1 linear  = 0 Cobb-Douglas  = -1 Leontief (rate allocation in a network)

  16. A CES Market • n buyers, with specified money • m divisible goods (unit amount) • Buyers have CES utility functions: Contains several interesting special cases:  = 1 linear  = 0 Cobb-Douglas  = -1 Leontief (rate allocation in a network)

  17. Market Equilibrium • n buyers, with specified money mi • m divisible goods (unit amount) • Buyers have CES utility functions: Find prices such that • buyers spend all their money • Market clears

  18. Market Equilibrium • Buyers’ optimization program: • Global Constraint:

  19. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program • The space of feasible allocations is: • How do you aggregate the utility functions U1, U2, … Un ?

  20. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program • The space of feasible allocations is: • How do you aggregate the utility functions U1, U2, … Un ? First observation: Adding them up is not the answer!

  21. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program Buyer i should not gain (or loose) by • Doubling all uij s • By splitting himself into two buyers with half of the money

  22. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program Buyer i should not gain (or loose) by • Doubling all uij s • By splitting himself into two buyers with half of the money • Eisenberg-Gale’s solution:

  23. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program

  24. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program • Optimum dual: Equilibrium prices (also unique) • Gives a poly-time algorithm for computing the equilibrium

  25. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program • Optimum dual: Equilibrium prices (also unique) • Gives a poly-time algorithm for computing the equilibrium • Market is “proportionally” fairfor every other allocation achieving

  26. Eisenberg-Gale’s convex program • Optimum dual: Equilibrium prices (also unique) • Gives a poly-time algorithm for computing the equilibrium • The program works for all homogenous utility functions, generalized to homothetic KVY 03(homothetic: U(f(y)) U is homogeneous of degree one and f is a monotone)

  27. x1 x2 x3 Application: Congestion Control

  28. $ $ $ Congestion Control Find the right prices in a Leontief market p1 = p2 = 3/2

  29. Congestion Control • Primal-dual scheme primal: packet rates at sources dual: congestion measures (shadow prices) A market equilibrium in a distributed setting! Kelly, Low, Doyle, Tan, ….

  30. Exchange Economy Agents buy and sell at the same time:

  31. Exchange Economy Agents buy and sell at the same time:  -1 -1 0 1 At least as hard as solving Nash Equilibria (CVSY 05) Polynomial-time algorithms known (DPSV 02, J 03, CMK 03 , GKV 04, ... OPEN!!

  32. Nash equilibria for a symmetric game H Finding the solution of LCP for H > 0 x is equilibrium if: Nash = Leontief Use LCP as an intermediate step:

  33. Finding the solution of LCP for H > 0 Nash = Leontief Leontief: H the rate matrix; agent i owns good i x is at equilibrium if:

  34. Open Questions • Exchange economies with -1 <  < -1 • Markets with indivisible goods • Price equilibria; proportional fair allocation • Core of a Game: • LP-based algorithm for transferable payoff • Still open for NTU games

  35. Nash = Leontief In Leontief markets, agents consume goods in fixed proportions: Let H > 0 be the utility matrix. Assume agent i owns good i x is an equilibrium if

More Related